• Refine Query
  • Source
  • Publication year
  • to
  • Language
  • 273
  • 17
  • 15
  • 3
  • 3
  • 2
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • Tagged with
  • 457
  • 457
  • 65
  • 63
  • 57
  • 55
  • 54
  • 52
  • 52
  • 49
  • 42
  • 40
  • 39
  • 38
  • 34
  • About
  • The Global ETD Search service is a free service for researchers to find electronic theses and dissertations. This service is provided by the Networked Digital Library of Theses and Dissertations.
    Our metadata is collected from universities around the world. If you manage a university/consortium/country archive and want to be added, details can be found on the NDLTD website.
11

LABOR LAW AND ECONOMICS: CASE STUDY OF THE NATIONAL LABOR RELATIONS ACT

PILL, MICHAEL 01 January 1983 (has links)
What is the relationship between economic crises and crises of the legal order? In both asking and attempting to answer that question, Marxian political economy provides the theoretical framework. The emphasis is on the establishment of collective bargaining under the control of a federal adminstrative agency--the National Labor Relations Board. The goal is to locate legal conflict in a theoretical framework explaining the production of legal doctrine in terms of class struggle, which is generated by crises in the process of capital accumulation. Analysis of legal authority (such as cases and statutes) using lawyers' reasoning by analogy and distinction demonstrates the internal dynamics of the production of legal doctrine in the United States. Legal conflict illuminates the economic, political and ideological conflicts of its time and place. Analysis of data on occurrence of strikes using social scientists' reasoning by statistical testing of hypothesized functional relationships demonstrates the Wagner Act's positive impact on organization of trade unions and the number of organizational strikes. There have been two great upsurges of class struggle in the United States during the past century--one from the 1890's through the First World War (the Progressive Era) and one from the 1930's through the Second World War (the era of F.D.R. and the New Deal). These periods have corresponded to crises in capital accumulation in which monopoly capitalists supported or at least accepted increased state intervention into the economy in order to rationalize and thereby reconstitute the accumulation process. In each of these cases, a crisis of capital accumulation generated class struggle in the workplace which in turn created a crisis of the legal order governing labor relations between workers and capitalists. The legal crisis leads to some new form of legal intervention into labor conflicts in order to help resolve the original accumulation crisis. However, the new legal framework which forms part of the solution to one crisis becomes part of the problem by the time the next accumulation crisis occurs.
12

GENDERED JOB TRAITS AND WOMEN'S OCCUPATIONS

ALEXANDER, JOSEPH DAVIDSON 01 January 1987 (has links)
Economic theories of occupational sex segregation are incomplete. They explain why women do not work in men's jobs, by referring to productivity traits which give men an advantage over women in the labor market. These explanations, however, preclude the possibility of persistent male unemployment coexisting with segregated women's occupations, because they imply that unemployed men, possessing superior labor market traits, could obtain women's positions. To allow for this coexistence of male unemployment and women working in segregated jobs and to correct several other lacunae in theories of women's work, this dissertation integrates a model of gendered job traits with models of labor markets. Four gender hypotheses accomplish this integration, centering on the hypothesis that many jobs themselves have gender identity in requiring job skills which are feminine, masculine or neutral. Job traits, moreover, change gender due to a variety of economic and cultural disturbances. Evidence supporting these hypotheses comes from statistical tests based on data from original surveys of teachers and restaurant waitpeople and from the history of clerical work. The hypotheses have significant implications for labor policies such as affirmative action and comparable worth. Legislated policy that promotes occupational integration, for example, may require a number of auxiliary policies to be effective. And implementing comparable worth policy faces a number of potential biases which we may diminish if we attend to gendered job traits in choosing compensable factors for job evaluation.
13

Essays in labor economics

Weber, Emily Anna 06 November 2021 (has links)
This dissertation consists of three chapters concerning the consequences of incarceration and performance pay for the modern US economy. The first two chapters consider the impact of the spatial location of prisons on two relevant groups: state prisoners and rural counties hosting state and federal prisons. The third chapter examines the relation between the incidence of performance pay in the labor market and the gender wage gap. The first chapter estimates the causal impact of offenders' distance from home during incarceration on later recidivism using a two-sample instrumental variables strategy. I instrument for an inmate’s distance from home with the average or minimum distance to state facilities from their home county, which varies across county and within county over time due to prison openings and closures. Doubling an inmate’s distance from home decreases the rate of 1-year recidivism by approximately 3 percentage points. Inmates convicted of a crime associated with membership in a criminal network experience the greatest decline in recidivism with distance. The second chapter assesses the effect of prisons on rural employment using a generalized difference-in-difference approach. The principal employment effect of prison openings and closures is a one-for-one gain or loss in public sector jobs. Prisons do not exert a local multiplier effect: employment in the private sector is generally unaffected by prison presence. Prisons thus appear to have little utility as a local development strategy and not to induce a county-level economic decline upon closure. The third chapter uses the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1997 to show that women are less likely to be in performance-pay jobs and experience a smaller earnings increase from participating in such jobs. I compare these findings with theoretical predictions of differing tastes for competition or biased subjective evaluation but find limited support that either factor explains most of the gender difference in performance pay. However, bonus-awarding jobs also demonstrate a higher elasticity of earnings with respect to weekly hours than other jobs do, and thus some of the wider wage gap is explained by gender differences in time at work.
14

Three essays on female labor supply and assortative mating

Gihleb, Rania 22 January 2016 (has links)
This thesis focuses on female labor supply, human capital and assortative mating. The first chapter examines the link between the gap in spousal education and the labor supply behavior of married women over the life-cycle. Based on data from the 1965-2011 March Current Population Surveys and the National Longitudinal Study of Youth 1979, it documents that, all else equal, if the wife's education exceeds her husband's then she is substantially more likely to be employed than if she is less educated than her husband (up to 14.5 percentage points). A dynamic life-cycle model of endogenous marriage and labor supply decisions in a collective framework is formulated and structurally estimated. It establishes that the link between a husband's educational attainment and a wife's labor supply decision, at the time of marriage, produces dynamic effects due to human capital accumulation and implied wage growth. Returns to experience account for 57 percent of the employment gap observed between women who had married "down" and those who married "up". Counterfactuals also indicate that, alone, the changes in assortative mating patterns across cohorts, which are implied by the changes in the marginal distributions of education, are able to explain a sizable proportion (roughly 25 percent) of the observed rise in married women's labor force participation. The second chapter analyzes the evolution of educational assortative mating along racial lines. Previous studies suggest that preferences have changed across cohorts in the US to produce an increase in assortative mating. The analysis in the second chapter challenges the metric of measurement for assortative mating and shows that educational assortative mating has been stable over time for blacks and whites despite social and economic changes that might have impacted individual's incentives to form a marriage. The third chapter proposes a novel instrument for catholic school attendance that exploits the abrupt shock to catholic schools' human capital in the aftermath of the second Vatican council. It shows that the positive correlation between Catholic schooling and student outcomes is explained by selection bias.
15

Social networks and labor market outcomes: Theoretical expansions and econometric analysis

Williams, Russell E 01 January 2004 (has links)
This study contributes to exploration and understanding of the role of social context in economic outcomes through expansion of theoretical and empirical work on the impact of social networks (ties between individuals and/or groups that are not mediated by markets). These ties can have substantial economic impact through their roles as information conduits, and through their influence on decision-making by job seekers and employers. Because social networks vary from person to person, they also play a major distributional role in conferring different opportunities among individuals. This dissertation expands the literature in labor market theory, and in the theory linking economic outcomes and social context, by providing new behavioral microfoundations for the impact of social networks in job search, extending the understanding of social network dynamics beyond the employer-initiated employee referral model introduced by Montgomery in 1989. The theory presented introduces two explanations of social network impact on labor market outcomes, an “early-bird” dynamic, and a “search-efficiency” dynamic. The early-bird effect reconciles survey answers more closely with theory, and fills an important gap in the explanation and interpretation of social network dynamics. The search-efficiency effect highlights another advantage of job-seekers with strong social networks. A unified framework for the conceptualization of job search success, incorporating social network effects, anticipated productivity, and discrimination is subsequently presented in Chapter 4. The dissertation's econometric analysis addresses issues of the absence of direct data on job search networks, and endogenous determination of an explanatory variable. Causal relationships advanced in theories of friendship formation are utilized to provide a necessary alternative structure to two-stage least squares analysis. Although the quality of the available data limits the conclusions that can be drawn from the econometric investigation, the study provides a strong base of theory for future inquiry and suggests that future research may contribute greatly to public policy.
16

Mandated wage floors and the wage structure: Analyzing the ripple effects of minimum and prevailing wage laws

Wicks-Lim, Jeannette 01 January 2005 (has links)
This dissertation empirically investigates the extent of ripple effects associated with changes in mandated wage floors in the United States. Ripple effects are generally theorized to exist because employers provide wage increases beyond those legally required in order to preserve a particular wage hierarchy. This research thus addresses an important policy question: What is the overall impact of mandated wage floors on the wage structure? I examine two types of mandated wage floors: federal and state minimum wage laws and state prevailing wage laws. I use a semi-parametric approach to estimate the wage effect of state and federal minimum wage changes at fourteen different wage percentiles. I find a limited minimum wage ripple effect. Workers earning up to the 15th wage percentile (within 135 percent of the minimum wage prior to the increase) experience a wage effect from minimum wage changes. Although limited in extent, these estimates imply a ripple effect multiplier of approximately 2.40 to 2.50. This expanded effect modestly improves the target efficiency of minimum wage laws. Also, because the wage growth of these lower wage percentiles lag the rest of the wage distribution in the absence of minimum wage changes, they appear to comprise a minimum wage contour. A separate analysis of the retail trade industry produces similar results. To observe prevailing wage law ripple effects, I estimate the wage effect of the repeal of state prevailing wage laws at five different points in the wage distribution using quantile regression. I use mean regression on samples of workers divided by union status and work experience to further specify the location of wage effects. The results suggest that prevailing wage laws produce limited or no ripple effects. The repeal of prevailing wage laws specifically impact the union wage premium of relatively more experienced construction workers and do not appear to spillover significantly to uncovered workers. The pattern of construction premiums across states suggests that prevailing wage laws may substitute as a source of bargaining power for union density.
17

The secondary labor segment and local labor markets

Kitchel, Marc C 01 January 1990 (has links)
Hypotheses drawn from labor segmentation literature concerning wage determination and the labor force characteristics of the secondary labor segment are tested on three local labor markets. Samples are constructed from Current Population Surveys from 1978 and 1985 for three metropolitan areas--Los Angeles-Long Beach, Philadelphia, and San Francisco-Oakland--and the procedure of David Gordon (1986) is used to identify the secondary segment. Estimation of a model predicting segment location produced mixed results. Controlling for a number of individual characteristics, there was evidence that African-American and Hispanic workers and youth were over-represented in the secondary segment. As the secondary segment was identified in this study, there was not evidence that women were over-represented in secondary employment, but women's wages were estimated to be substantially lower in both non-secondary and secondary employment. Ordinary least squares estimation of earnings determination showed mixed support for the existence of labor segmentation with estimated returns to education significantly lower in the secondary sector in five of the six metropolitan samples and estimated returns to labor market experience significantly lower in four. However, the return to the head-of-household variable--a proxy for labor force attachment--was only significantly lower in one of the samples. Comparisons of estimated relative wages for various demographic groups indicated generally lower earnings for secondary jobs, but there were notable anomalies in the 1978 Philadelphia sample. A switching model with known regimes was employed to test and correct for potential selection bias in ordinary least squares estimation of the earnings structure. Estimates obtained from a conventional modelling of selectivity provided limited and inconsistent evidence of selection bias and suggested the limited appropriateness of the model. The study includes consideration of factors which may have contributed to the inconsistency of the results, including data limitations, segment misclassification, and the conceptualization of race and ethnicity and gender relations within a static model of labor segmentation.
18

Human Response to Residential Crowding: An Analysis of Dormitory Environments

Zanter, Friedhelm January 1980 (has links)
No description available.
19

Essays in Labor Economics:

Bhagia, Divya January 2022 (has links)
Thesis advisor: Theodore TP Papageorgiou / This dissertation contains three independent chapters on topics in labor economics. In the first chapter, I examine the sources of decline in the job-finding rate over the spell of unemployment. In particular, I distinguish between dynamic selection and the adverse effect of longer unemployment durations. In the second chapter, Carter Bryson and I explore the role of broad sectoral shifts in labor demand in explaining the divergence of employment outcomes of Black and White men during the second half of the 20th century. Finally, in the third chapter, I propose a nonparametric estimator for the discrete-time version of the Mixed Proportional Hazard (MPH). In the first chapter, "Duration Dependence and Heterogeneity: Learning from Early Notice of Layoff,'' I disentangle the sources of decline in the observed job-finding rate over the spell of unemployment. It is possible that an individual worker's likelihood of exiting unemployment declines with the duration of unemployment (e.g., due to employers discriminating against long-term unemployed). However, workers also differ in their employability, their desperation to find a job, or perhaps their ability to look for jobs. Such heterogeneity across workers, which is often unobserved, implies that the observed job-finding rate declines even when an individual worker's exit probability does not. As the more employable workers exit early, the still unemployed workers are increasingly the less employable ones. A long literature tries to disentangle the role of structural duration dependence from heterogeneity, but it has proved to be quite challenging. I develop and implement a novel approach to answer this question by leveraging variation in the length of notice an individual receives from their previous employer before being laid off. The key idea behind my approach is that workers with longer notice start searching earlier and are more likely to exit unemployment early. If workers are heterogeneous, then the composition of long-notice workers should be worse at later durations as the more employable workers from this group have already left. This observation enables me to pin down the extent of heterogeneity and estimate structural duration dependence. My estimates imply that there is substantial heterogeneity in the likelihood of exiting unemployment across workers. I find that roughly 40% of the decline in the observed job-finding rate over the first five months is due to dynamic selection. Further, an individual's exit probability increases up to unemployment insurance (UI) exhaustion and remains constant after that. This is in contrast to the observed exit rate, which continues to decline even after benefit exhaustion. Recently, researchers have tried to explain this decline in the observed exit rate after UI exhaustion. For instance, it can be rationalized with storable offers (Boone and van Ours, 2012) or reference-dependent utility (DellaVigna et. al., 2017). My estimates suggest that most of the decline in the observed exit rate after UI exhaustion is due to changes in the composition of workers. In the second chapter which is joint work with Carter Bryson, "Understanding the Racial Employment Gap: The Role of Sectoral Shifts,'' we quantify the extent to which sectoral reallocation can explain the divergence in employment outcomes of Black and White men during the last three decades of the 20th century. Using a shift-share strategy, we document that local employment-to-population ratios for Black men are relatively more responsive to local labor demand shocks. We also document substantial population responses for both groups of workers. Finally, we provide a framework incorporating frictional unemployment and imperfect mobility across locations to aggregate these local responses. We find that sectoral shifts can explain roughly half of the observed exacerbation in the employment-to-population ratio differential between Black and White workers from 1970 to 2000. Furthermore, our findings indicate that the increase in the differential due to sectoral shifts results from the greater responsiveness of Black workers to local labor demand shifts rather than a higher concentration of these shifts in areas or sectors with a higher share of Black workers. In the final chapter, "The Discrete-Time Mixed Proportional Hazard Model'', I propose a nonparametric estimator for the discrete-time MPH model. Hazard models of event durations are widely employed in economics to analyze unemployment spells, retirement decisions, and an array of other topics. As the findings from the first chapter highlight, ignoring unobserved heterogeneity while analyzing duration data can lead to inaccurate inferences. The MPH model explicitly accounts for such heterogeneity but estimating this model can be challenging. I set up a discrete-time MPH model and propose an estimator for it that is based on the Generalized Method of Moments and is easy to implement. / Thesis (PhD) — Boston College, 2022. / Submitted to: Boston College. Graduate School of Arts and Sciences. / Discipline: Economics.
20

Parental Bargaining and Gender Gap in Primary Education Expenditure

Gao, Qianyun 01 January 2017 (has links)
This paper examines the gender gap in human capital investment in India from the perspective of intra-household bargaining. I test whether the existing gender disparity in bargaining power, in the form of educational attainment of parents, contributes to the differences in educational expenditure between sons and daughters. As the proxy for bargaining power, fathers’ and mothers’ educational attainments both have a positive impact on the human capital investment for the children, but the gender gap widens with fathers’ education and narrows with mothers’. The results are robust controlling for additional variables such as age, number of siblings, household income, caste and location. These findings suggest that mothers may have a preference for daughters’ education. When their bargaining power rises, families tend to spend more equal amounts on the education of daughters and sons. Policies aiming at improving gender equality in education should take into account the decision-making process.

Page generated in 0.0602 seconds