Spelling suggestions: "subject:"landreform"" "subject:"antireform""
51 |
Community-based sustainable tourism on commonages an alternative to traditional land reform in Namaqualand, Northern Cape Province /Govender-Van Wyk, Sharmla. January 2006 (has links)
Thesis (PhD(Tourism Management))--University of Pretoria, 2006. / Abstract in English and Afrikaans. Includes bibliographical references. Available on the Internet via the World Wide Web.
|
52 |
Land reform and the fall of the Roman Republic, 133-83 BCHanna, Michael. Hamilton, Jeffrey S. January 2006 (has links)
Thesis (M.A.)--Baylor University, 2006. / Includes bibliographical references (p. 95-97).
|
53 |
Land reform in the news: An analysis of how certain South African newspapers covered land reform before and after the 2005 National Land SummitGenis, Amelia Jasmine January 2006 (has links)
Philosophiae Doctor - PhD / This thesis investigates land reform coverage at the time of the land summit through quantitative and qualitative content analysis. Hard news reports, editorials and opinion pieces that appeared in the daily newspapers Beeld, Business day, Sowetan and Sunday newspapers Rapport and Sunday Times between July and September 2005 were analysed in terms of what they reported , issues that received little attention, portrayal of certain issues and sources used. The findings were used to make inference about the degree to which the newspapers in the study fulfill their societal roles. / South Africa
|
54 |
The modern northwestern ejido under mexican agrarian reformMcAlley, Peter Quentin January 1971 (has links)
Mexican Land Reform, conceived during the civil war and initiated in the Revolutionary Code of 1917, is responsible for the existence today of three different farming groups. These are the particulares, the private farmers, the ejidatarios, the peasant farmers, and the colonos, the colonist farmers. This study is concerned with the relative fortunes of the three, and especially with the largest numerically, the ejidatarios. This last group has been regarded, and is still so considered, as the worst off. The plight of the ejidatarios seems to be even more acute in modernized areas according to State and national statistics. It is hypothesized here that certain aspects of the Mexican Land Reform work against the better interests of the ejidatarios, particularly in areas where modernized agricultural practices have become the norm. The hypothesis is tested in one of the agriculturally most advanced areas in all Mexico, the Rio Fuerte Irrigation District of Northern Sinaloa. Within this District the performance of the Mexican ejido, peasant holding, is compared with that of the private property farm.
The comparison begins with an investigation of all cropping activities in the District, designed to establish the broad differences in performance between the ejidal and private farm groups (Chapter III). It is found:- that the ejidal sector operates its cropland less intensively than the private sector; that the ejidatarios do not compensate for their poorer resource use by obtaining crop yields and prices markedly superior to those of the private sector; and that the ejidatarios obtain a much lower gross income per hectare than the private farmers.
In the second stage of comparison, a sample of farms is taken from the most productive sub-area in the District, in order to test the hypothesis and to try to isolate the primary factors hindering the ejidal sector (Chapter IV). The farms selected consist of the ejidal plots where wheat is cultivated in the main crop rotation; and for the purposes of comparing net incomes, wheat-growing private and colono farms are also sampled. It is found that the mean net income per hectare is much lower in the ejidal than in the other two sectors. This cannot be entirely explained by poorer quality land resources, ineptitude, lack of hybrid seed or fertilizer, or by shortage of irrigation water. Nor can it be entirely explained by its somewhat poorer overall yield. Rather is the problem found to be in the nature of the ejidatarios' credit source, the Ejidal Banks, and the operational constraints associated with that source's loan policy. It is shown that the cost of ejidal farm operation is unnecessarily high, because the ejidatarios are not permitted efficient use of their own labour resources; hired labour and machinery are supplied by the Banks to the ejidatarios to cultivate their land and these inappropriated high-cost inputs are charged within the loans given.,
It is concluded that overmuch modernization is being forced upon the peasant farmers, to the ultimate detriment of their farm's viability, their personal income and living levels, and also that the hypothesis is correct:- The Agrarian Reform Laws have indeed led to operational difficulties and considerable depression of the peasant farmer's net income, though the particular credit system evolved was actually created to benefit him. / Arts, Faculty of / Geography, Department of / Graduate
|
55 |
Fast track land reform and belonging: examining linkages between resettlement areas and communal areas in Zvimba District, ZimbabweMarewo, Malvern Kudakwashe January 2020 (has links)
This study examines whether beneficiaries of Zimbabwe's Fast Track Land Reform Programme (FTLRP) of 2000 in resettlement areas maintain linkages with communal areas of origin. Present studies about the FTLRP provide limited in-depth attention to the importance of understanding linkages with places of origin. The study sought to explore the extent to which beneficiaries of the FTLRP are connected to their communal areas of origin, as well as the implications of the ties. Analysis of linkages is through social relationships and labour exchanges between people in resettlement areas and communal areas. This was done through a conceptual framework of belonging, which helped explain the various attachments to places of origin. The study was guided by a qualitative research approach. A case study of Machiroli Farm, an A1 villagised settlement, and Zvimba communal areas (Ward 6), Mashonaland West, Zimbabwe was utilised. The study's main finding is that beneficiaries of the FTLRP in the A1 model on Machiroli Farm retain linkages with communal areas of origin; beneficiaries of the FTLRP acquired new land without discarding ties and relations with places of origin. Most respondents attached clear importance to maintaining linkages with places of origin. Some respondents did not maintain ties with places of origin because of conflicts and breakdowns in family ties, highlighting that belonging is not static. Evidence from this case study shows that maintenance of linkages assists with agricultural production and enhancing social relations. Another important finding is that belonging enforced the maintenance of relations through factors, such as familial relations, burial sites, clubs, ceremonies and labour exchanges with communal areas of origin. The study argues that belonging is an aspect that ties people together despite physical translocation. Thus, this study's contribution is that, within land reform debates, physical translocation does not break the bonds with, or ties to, places of origin. Belonging enables several functions, such as access to labour, mitigation of economic challenges and enhancement of social relations, as demonstrated by this case study. For scholarship, the study contributes to land reform debates by applying the concept of belonging, which has mostly been applied to border and migration studies policy. The framework of belonging within land reform reveals the importance of social, cultural, religious and economic effects in accessing labour and enhancing agricultural production in agrarian settings. The study draws the conclusion that beneficiaries of land reform desire to remain relevant to a host of political, economic, spiritual and social aspects anchored in places of origin. Therefore, resettlement does not break ties which people have with places of origin, people embrace the new without discarding the old relations.
|
56 |
The political economy of Chinese agrarian development policies: 1949-1964Bain, Agnes Sapienza January 1978 (has links)
China is a modernizing agrarian society. As such, it
pursued certain goals within an environment of resource scarcity.
This research analyzes Chinese public policies for agrarian development
within a framework of political economy. It begins with the
hypothesis that resources, (material output, infrastructure,
political legitimacy, etc.), can be politicized such that their values
becane relative within a single costs/benefits framework". The exchange
of resources between the regime and social sectors is reflected in
public policy.
The hypothesis is tested in a longitudinal case study of
Chinese agrarian policies, extending from 1949 through 1964. During
this period, Chinese decision makers focused on the agrarian sector
and its role in the attainment of national goals. Therefore, within
this time frame, the dynamics of resource creation, investment and
exchange can be traced through the agrarian policy matrix to demonstrate
the utility of this model.
When resources are politicized they are brought into a
"political market" where they become available for use. The first
step toward the creation of this market is the politicization of
existing resources. In China, this was effected by land reform and
by the creation of infrastructure to penetrate and control the rural
marketplace itself.
As the political market expands, it also becomes more complex,
generating greater demands for all types of resources. Chinese collectivization
policies reorganized the internal resources of the agrarian
sector -- land and labor -- in order to increase their productivity.
However, internal resources proved insufficient for agrarian modernization
and the collective infrastructure proved costly in terms of
political and social resources. Therefore, communization was adopted
as an alternative pattern of resource use and investment.
The size, functional scope and structural efficiency of the
commune were designed to maximize the use-value of internal agrarian
resources. But its high risk component was the introduction of a
division of labor into the rural environment. Differentiation and
specialization in the production process would destroy traditional
socio-economic units which were functionally integrated. In terms of
the political market, these policies would secure and control the
availability and value of agrarian resources.
The immediate costs of rapid, qualitative change quickly
surpassed long-term benefits. During' the crisis period of 1959-1961,
the division of labor was withdrawn, along with all but the, administrative functions of the commune. However, political inflation,
followed by a drastic deflation, resulted in the collapse of the
political market. Still seeking workable alternatives for resource
utilization, the regime combined agrarian "self-reliance" with
selective technological and capital investments. This strategy
promised differentiated development within the sector and a perpetual
rural/urban dichotomy. As such, it was opposed by the "Maoist"
faction. Reconsolidation policies -- rebuilding the political
market -- became infused with an ideological debate. Out of this
struggle there emerged a workable and essentially Maoist approach --
the Dazhai model -- which created a supportive environment for long term
agrarian development.
The political economy of agrarian development energes when
these policies are viewed within a single costs/benefits framework.
Long range goals were held constant by ideology while intermediate
aims were pursued by evaluating and exchanging resources, and by
choosing among options for resource utilization and investment. The
agrarian policy matrix between 1949 and 1964 thus emerges as complex
and non-linear. But it is developmental, in that the aggregate level
of resource availability and political productivity was increased.
|
57 |
The role of social capital in the Fast Track Land Reform Programme (FTLRP) of Zimbabwe: a case of Rouxdale (R/E) Farm, Bubi District, Matabeleland North ProvinceNcube, Senzeni 19 February 2019 (has links)
This study investigates the role of social capital towards the realisation of the positive benefits of land through the A1 crop-based villagised model of the Fast Track Land Reform Programme (FTLRP), which has been largely viewed as successful in academic literature. The study emerges out of a large gap in scholarly literature, which largely side-lines social outcomes of the FTLRP while focusing mostly on material outcomes. The study contributes to limited research on the non-material outcomes in the Matabeleland North Province, an under researched area in the subject of land reform in Zimbabwe. Thus, social capital was selected to investigate these non-visible outcomes of FTLRP. A qualitative research design was used, with semi-structured interviews, informal conversations, observation, archives and secondary literature being the main sources of data. The study focused on a single case study, beneficiaries of Rouxdale (R/E) farm in Bubi District. The study brings the following insights: first, social capital played a pivotal role in accessing land. Second, ordinary people acquired land. Third, women were empowered through access to land. Fourth, land is an asset whose benefits far surpass livelihood creation. Fifth, land reform models have an impact on social capital. The main contribution of the study is that social capital promotes solidarity and the tackling of collective problems in land reform models with a communal component. The study illustrates that social capital creates a conducive environment for the attainment of the benefits of land. This is facilitated by beneficiaries’ effort to maintain healthy social network relationships. The study demonstrates that various decisions of the state have a potential of hindering social capital in resettlement areas through the destruction of social network relationships, such that its positive impact becomes limited. This portrays the fragile nature of social capital, which can easily be destroyed by external negative factors, regardless of the length of time taken in establishing it. Social capital can be applied in different spheres. However, its outcomes are directly informed by different contexts, thus making it context specific in nature. The study stresses that governments that use social capital in land reform should be conscious of local contextual dynamics before developing programmes that affect beneficiaries, in order to preserve existing social network relationships. The fragility and context specific nature of social capital is missing in the conceptualisation of its main scholars, yet they emerge as important aspects in this study. The study points to the need for these to be incorporated into the core elements of the concept of social capital to create a more holistic framework of analysis. The study therefore argues that social capital is vital in land reform and the post-settlement phase.
|
58 |
Fast track land reform programmes and household food security : case of Mutare district (Zimbabwe)Mudefi, Rwadzisai Abraham 11 1900 (has links)
The research attempted to demystify the Zimbabwean land reform that was spear headed by war veterans’ in Zimbabwe. This research investigated the impact of the Fast Track Land Reform Programme (FTLRP) in 2000 on Household Food Security. It was generally assumed that the programme did not improve Household Food Security. To verify that assertion the research used questionnaires in a survey research design. The questionnaires were administered to 322 household heads that had been selected by the random stratified sampling method in Mutare District. The results established that Household Food Security in Mutare District improved after the implementation of the FTLRP. The national grain storage however was depleted because the new farmers reduced the production levels set by the former white farmers. The research therefore recommends an orderly and sustainable transition of Land Reform in future programmes to enhance national grain reserves. This also further improves the Household Food Security.
|
59 |
Land tenure innovations in rural development the problems in western Nigeria with some Tanzanian comparisons.Fabiyi, Yakub Layiwola. January 1974 (has links)
Thesis (Ph. D.)--University of Wisconsin--Madison, 1974. / Typescript. Vita. eContent provider-neutral record in process. Description based on print version record. Includes bibliographical references.
|
60 |
Geographies of land restitution in Northern Limpopo place, territory, and class /Fraser, Alistair, January 2006 (has links)
Thesis (Ph. D.)--Ohio State University, 2006. / Title from first page of PDF file. Includes bibliographical references (p. 179-187).
|
Page generated in 0.2184 seconds