Spelling suggestions: "subject:"real property - derices."" "subject:"real property - caprices.""
41 |
Influence of Hong Kong investment on prices and design of houses in VancouverHui, William, 許嘉偉 January 1990 (has links)
published_or_final_version / Urban Design / Master / Master of Urban Design
|
42 |
Major factors contributing to rising residential property prices in Hong KongChan, Siu-kuen., 陳少娟. January 1996 (has links)
published_or_final_version / Housing Management / Master / Master of Housing Management
|
43 |
Impacts of public housing on neighbourhood land value譚慧玲, Tam, Wai-ling, Vivian. January 1995 (has links)
published_or_final_version / Urban Design / Master / Master of Urban Design
|
44 |
Mortgage finance: its impact on private residential property prices in Hong KongNarayanamurthy, T. R. January 1995 (has links)
published_or_final_version / Urban Design / Master / Master of Urban Design
|
45 |
Influence of land supply on rising residential prices: including implication for urban design譚彥斌, Tam, Yin-bun, Eric. January 1993 (has links)
published_or_final_version / Urban Design / Master / Master of Urban Design
|
46 |
The multiple and conflicting roles of local government in negotiating parkland acquisition : can the negotiations satisfy the criteria of ethics and the dimensions of interests?Schlesinger, Gerald 05 1900 (has links)
The practice of providing urban parks as an integral part of community development no
longer creates public debate about the function or legal authority of local governments to make
such purchases. However, the debate continues on the ethics of local government's parkland
acquisition practices. These practices have the capability and motivation to influence the land
value of sites they wish to acquire. Local governments are responsible for determining land
use, which in turn affects land value. The limited financial means of local government to
acquire parks makes influencing land value one way of stretching the scarce resources of the
community.
The ethics practiced in the negotiations to acquire urban parkland where the land has
development potential are unique because:
1. Parkland is a public good and not a market commodity;
2. The potential for other higher land uses exists; and
3. Local government plays a dual role: one of a regulator and approving authority for
determining land use and providing community stewardship, and the other as the
corporate cost controlling agency seeking to acquire land.
These qualities create the strong possibility for ethical conflict to occur in the negotiating
process.
Building upon the Interest-Based approach to negotiations, this paper uses a set of
Prescriptive, Intuitive and Evaluative (P.I.E.) criteria that define ethical conduct, and the
dimensions of Fact, Social Consensus and Experience that defines the dimensions of interests,
to develop a General Model for Ethical Negotiations (GMEN). Conceptually, the GMEN
model is a three-sided pyramid within a sphere of negotiations. Negotiations that adhere to the
principles defining the parameters of the pyramid would be considered ethical. Negotiations
outside the pyramid are considered unethical.
Six parkland acquisition cases are discussed using the GMEN model. In this study, the
parameters establishing the criteria for passing ethical judgment are the functions of the
political economy, the policy statements of the local government, and the legislation that
delegates power and authority to local government.
The study finds that ethical conflict is inherent in parkland negotiations where the land
has development potential because of the multiple roles and dual character of local government.
This conflict is not necessarily illegal since prescriptive criteria are only one means of judging
ethics. Nor is the outcome necessarily negative to the vendor, since the public may end up with
a less attractive park agreement. However, the parameters that would require parkland
acquisition negotiations to be ethical sometimes conflict with some of the multiple roles held by
local government. Several recommendations are made that would help to reduce ethical
conflict and the imbalance in parkland negotiations.
|
47 |
Determining the Impact of Selected Variables on the Sale Price of Real EstateMartin, Jon E. (Jon Egan) 05 1900 (has links)
This paper presents the results of a study dealing with a number of issues regarding real estate investment. Utilizing a data set consisting of real estate transactions, questions relative to the impact of certain variables on the sale price are addressed. This analysis addresses the question of the impact of financial, physical, and location characteristics on the sales price of commercial grade real estate.
|
48 |
The multiple and conflicting roles of local government in negotiating parkland acquisition : can the negotiations satisfy the criteria of ethics and the dimensions of interests?Schlesinger, Gerald 05 1900 (has links)
The practice of providing urban parks as an integral part of community development no
longer creates public debate about the function or legal authority of local governments to make
such purchases. However, the debate continues on the ethics of local government's parkland
acquisition practices. These practices have the capability and motivation to influence the land
value of sites they wish to acquire. Local governments are responsible for determining land
use, which in turn affects land value. The limited financial means of local government to
acquire parks makes influencing land value one way of stretching the scarce resources of the
community.
The ethics practiced in the negotiations to acquire urban parkland where the land has
development potential are unique because:
1. Parkland is a public good and not a market commodity;
2. The potential for other higher land uses exists; and
3. Local government plays a dual role: one of a regulator and approving authority for
determining land use and providing community stewardship, and the other as the
corporate cost controlling agency seeking to acquire land.
These qualities create the strong possibility for ethical conflict to occur in the negotiating
process.
Building upon the Interest-Based approach to negotiations, this paper uses a set of
Prescriptive, Intuitive and Evaluative (P.I.E.) criteria that define ethical conduct, and the
dimensions of Fact, Social Consensus and Experience that defines the dimensions of interests,
to develop a General Model for Ethical Negotiations (GMEN). Conceptually, the GMEN
model is a three-sided pyramid within a sphere of negotiations. Negotiations that adhere to the
principles defining the parameters of the pyramid would be considered ethical. Negotiations
outside the pyramid are considered unethical.
Six parkland acquisition cases are discussed using the GMEN model. In this study, the
parameters establishing the criteria for passing ethical judgment are the functions of the
political economy, the policy statements of the local government, and the legislation that
delegates power and authority to local government.
The study finds that ethical conflict is inherent in parkland negotiations where the land
has development potential because of the multiple roles and dual character of local government.
This conflict is not necessarily illegal since prescriptive criteria are only one means of judging
ethics. Nor is the outcome necessarily negative to the vendor, since the public may end up with
a less attractive park agreement. However, the parameters that would require parkland
acquisition negotiations to be ethical sometimes conflict with some of the multiple roles held by
local government. Several recommendations are made that would help to reduce ethical
conflict and the imbalance in parkland negotiations. / Applied Science, Faculty of / Community and Regional Planning (SCARP), School of / Graduate
|
49 |
Essays in Spatial and International EconomicsZhang, Howard Zihao January 2023 (has links)
This dissertation contains four essays in spatial and international economics.
Chapter 1 investigates how housing variety varies across space. Housing costs are key in understanding real income differences across space and time. Standard measures of housing costs do not account for availability differences, where some housing varieties are available in certain cities or time periods but not others. When households have idiosyncratic preferences over housing units, the set of available housing varieties in a city matters. This paper develops theoretically-founded housing price indices to measure housing costs that account for availability differences. To allow for flexible substitution patterns, I propose a method to jointly estimate the nests that varieties belong to and the elasticity of substitution across varieties within each nest. I find that households in larger cities benefit from having access to varieties not available in smaller cities. Utility-consistent housing prices reduce the elasticity of housing prices with respect to population by a half. Since housing is a third of household expenditure, this implies that we have systematically underestimated real income and overestimated residual amenities in larger cities. In contrast to previous estimates, I find that real income is increasing in city size after accounting for availability differences.
Chapter 2 investigates the factors that cause incomplete pass-through of exchange rate shocks into border prices. This paper examines the role of decreasing returns to scale, a channel that has received limited empirical and theoretical attention. Based on a first-order approximation to a firm's optimal price, I show that 1) decreasing returns to scale interacts with variable markups, imported inputs, and destination non-traded costs to generate incomplete pass-through, 2) there is asymmetry between importer currency and exporter currency shocks due to imported inputs, and 3) strategic complementarity matters, where firms adjust their prices in response to competitor prices. I propose a new estimation method for key demand and supply parameters that govern the degree of markup and marginal cost adjustments. Using the estimated parameters, I find that decreasing returns to scale is the dominant factor in generating incomplete pass-through, with variable marginal costs contributing to over 90% of the incomplete pass-through, while variable markups account for less than 10%.
Chapter 3 analyzes the determinants of exporter size. Theories of comparative advantage and product differentiation have emphasized productivity and quality differences. This paper shows that incorporating decreasing returns to scale matters for understanding the determinants of exporter size. Exogenous marginal cost differences affect equilibrium quantities but do not necessarily appear in prices since lower exogenous marginal costs (a lower cost curve) are offset by higher endogenous marginal costs (movement along the cost curve). As a result, standard approaches that assume constant returns to scale underestimate the contribution of marginal cost differences and overestimate the contribution of quality differences. Based on bilateral trade flow data between 1997 to 2016 for over 200 countries and 3000 products, I find that standard approaches attribute almost no variation in exporter size to cost differences. In contrast, after incorporating decreasing returns to scale, I estimate that 58% (65%) of the variation in exporter size is attributed to fundamental cost differences in the time series (cross-section).
Chapter 4 models and quantifies the dynamic gains from exporting. I develop a dynamic trade model where firms innovate and learn from other firms in the destinations they sell to. The evolution of a country's stock of knowledge can be expressed as a function of export flows and the stocks of knowledge of their trading partners. I find evidence that countries in Asia, North America, and Europe, as well as countries in the top two quartiles of TFP growth were able to better absorb foreign insights than other countries. I evaluate whether there are dynamic gains from trade with two counterfactual exercises. First, I measure the impact of changing trade costs between 1962 and 2000. I find small static gains but zero dynamic gains for the world economy. Second, I quantify the dynamic gains from export-induced foreign knowledge flows by simulating a counterfactual where there is no learning from foreign sources. I find that domestic learning compensates for foreign learning: there are large dynamic gains from exporting when there is no domestic learning and small dynamic gains when there is domestic learning.
|
50 |
A study of the relationship between changes in housing values and variations in macroeconomic factorsHaworth, Martin January 2007 (has links)
A Research Report
presented to the
Graduate School of Business Leadership
University of South Africa.
In partial fulfilment of the
requirements for the
MASTERS DEGREE IN BUSINESS LEADERSHIP,
UNIVERSITY OF SOUTH AFRICA / The purpose of this research is to analyse the changes in housing values in
Windhoek, Namibia over the past ten years and explore links in property value
variation to macroeconomic changes during that period. The objectives of this
research are twofold. Firstly this research compiles and assesses the movement of
housing values over the past ten years. Secondly this research assesses if there is a
causal relationship between changes in macroeconomic factors and housing values,
and to define the nature of this relationship. The timing and magnitude of response
by housing values to changes in macroeconomic factors are investigated.
The primary data requirements for this study are a monthly relative value index of
housing prices for the Windhoek area and macroeconomic factors. Macroeconomic
data collected relates to macroeconomic conditions within Namibia that could have
an effect on housing prices. This includes information on housing supply, GDP,
population levels, inflation and interest rates. The results of this study explore the
relationship between these factors and changes in housing prices as reflected by
changes in the housing index.
The most significant result of this study is the effect of housing availability on housing
values. Changes in the total supply of housing as estimated by the number of
houses built in a month affect changes in housing values after 5 and 6 months. A
total of 20.5% of the change in housing values can be explained by the change in
total housing supply. The effect of interest rates found by this study was lower than
the theory and literature reviews would have led us to expect. The results of the
Pearson correlation test for the relationship between percentage changes in interest
rates and percentage changes in future housing values found that a relationship
exists 8 months after the change in interest rates occurred. Interest rates were found
to explain 5.5% of the change in housing values 8 months later.
No significant effects were noted for changes in inflation. For population and income
changes there was insufficient data to perform more than a high level look at
possible interactions with the level of housing prices. / Graduate School of Business Leadership / MBL
|
Page generated in 0.1168 seconds