Spelling suggestions: "subject:" conomic aspects"" "subject:" c:conomic aspects""
231 |
Estimation of net economic benefits of the Oregon big game resource to huntersShalloof, Faisal M. 22 April 1981 (has links)
Much outdoor recreation occurs on publicly owned land and water
resources, or involves use of these public resources. Consequently, an
economic problem arises concerning the value of recreational resources
which do not have a conventional market price. Without a price to guide
the allocation of resources, it is difficult to obtain optimal decisions
in allocation of these publicly owned natural resources among alternative
uses, including recreation, timber, and domestic livestock production.
In Oregon, the big game resource has a great impact on the economy
of the state. Positive values of this resource are related to recreational
use and to income generated which benefit local economies. Negative
values of big game include its competition for resources used for
timber production and/or livestock grazing.
In order to better assess the value of the big game resource, an
attempt has been made in this thesis to improve demand models from which
the net economic value of the Oregon big game resource can be derived.
The data used in this study were obtained from the questionnaires mailed
to a random sample of Oregon big game hunters during the fall of 1968.
The travel cost method was used to estimate the demand for big game
hunting, based on the actual behavior of the hunters. Several algebraic
forms of the travel cost demand equation were estimated for the Northeast
and the Central regions of Oregon.
The concept of consumers' surplus was used to estimate the net economic
value for the Oregon big game resources. Net economic value for
the Northeast and Central regions of Oregon in 1968 dollars was approximately
$14.3 million, based on the exponential demand function. Net
economic value for the same two regions was approximately $11 million,
based on the linear demand function.
An attempt was made in this study to predict the changes in consumers'
surplus from changes in the number of deer and elk harvested.
Note that the regression models in this thesis implied that a ten percent
increase in harvest would increase the consumers' surplus of
hunters by more than ten percent. However, the hypothesis that a ten
percent increase in harvest would increase consumers' surplus by exactly
ten percent was not rejected by a statistical test. Therefore, a good
deal more research is needed to determine the value of marginal changes
in the number of deer and elk harvested.
It is thought that the estimation of net economic value in this
study for the Northeast and Central regions of Oregon will be useful
from the viewpoint of big game management and resource allocation in
Oregon. / Graduation date: 1981
|
232 |
An econometric analysis of the demand for selected agricultural inputs in OregonYadav, Ram Prakash 27 July 1971 (has links)
The objective of this study is to analyze empirically the demand
structure for the following important farm production inputs in
Oregon: hired labor, chemical fertilizer, farm machinery, repairs
and operating costs of motor vehicles and other machinery designated
as "machinery supplies," purchased feed and miscellaneous inputs.
Twenty-year data (1950-69 except 1951-70 for hired labor)
were analyzed with the aid of simple equation least-squares multiple
regression techniques for all inputs. In addition, a simultaneous-equation
model is applied to hired labor data. The demand for each
input is predicted through 1975.
This study indicates that hired farm labor employment depends
heavily upon wage rates. Contrary to earlier national and regional
studies, the short-run demand for hired farm labor in Oregon during
1951-70 was found to be elastic, -1.2 to -1.5 and -1.5 to -2.6 in
the single-equation and the simultaneous-equation demand models
respectively. This implies that if farm wage rates rise, the number
of workers employed declines in greater proportion than the wage rate
rise. Conversely, if wage rates fall the number of workers
employed will increase disproportionately. The number of hired
workers employed on Oregon farms declined by 40.6 percent (37
thousand to 22 thousand) between 1950 and 1970. A further 25 percent
decline is projected by 1975.
The demand for fertilizer and purchased feed are comparable
in many ways. The demand for each is inelastic (-0.45 and -0.58)
in the short-run, and moderately elastic (-1.05 to -1.35) in the long-run.
The adjustment coefficient, which indicates the percent of the
required adjustment that can be made in one year in feed or fertilizer
purchases, in both cases are about the same--around 0.50.
However, profitability of livestock enterprises as an independent
variable (RL subscript [t]) is statistically significant in the demand equation for
purchased feed, but profitability of farming as a variable (R subscript [t]) is not
significant in the fertilizer models. Furthermore, fertilizer
purchases continued to increase in spite of static or slightly
decreasing crop prices. Although the input price variable is
statistically significant in the demand models for both fertilizer
and purchased feed, decreasing fertilizer prices have probably
contributed heavily to the increase in the use of fertilizers in
Oregon.
If the past declining trend in the "real" price of fertilizer continues
and other relationships do not change materially, there will
be a 43 percent (381.8 thousand tons to 547.5 thousand tons)
greater consumption of fertilizer in Oregon over the next six years.
Based on past experience, such an increase is undoubtedly within
the capability of the fertilizer industry to meet the requirement.
The expenditure for purchased feed is projected to be 9 percent
greater in 1975 than in 1969 in terms of constant 1957-59 dollars.
The increase becomes 25 percent when expressed in terms of what
feed prices are expected to be in 1975 dollars.
Unavailability of data on annual capital outlay for the purchase
of machinery and equipment by Oregon farmers is a serious problem
in the estimation of the demand structure for farm machinery.
However, annual inventories of machinery and equipment on Oregon
farms is used as a substitute variable. The analysis indicates the
demand for machinery and equipment inventories to be inelastic.
The demand for "machinery supplies", a variable with considerable
complementarity with machinery and equipment inventory, was also
found to be inelastic. A 10 percent increase in the price of farm
machinery or price of "machinery supplies" is associated with a
4.5 percent decrease in the total machinery and equipment inventory,
and a 6.3 percent decrease in "machinery supplies" purchased.
The estimated elasticities may be biased due to high multi-collinearity
problems in their demand models. However, the
prediction ability of these models is undoubtedly good. It is expected
that there will be a $32 million increase (1957-59 dollars)
in the value of machinery inventories on Oregon farms by 1975 over
the 1969 level. The increase is $104 million in 1975 dollars. The
expenditure for repairs and operating costs of motor vehicles and
other machinery (machinery supplies) are expected to be fairly
constant during this period in terms of 1957-59 dollars. This
peculiarity of increasing inventory of machinery and equipment in
1957-59 dollars and a constant expenditure for "machinery supplies"
is judged to be due to the fact that the machinery inventory effect
and the price effect seem to cancel out and maintain the constant
expenditure for "machinery supplies." Prices of "machinery
supplies" have tended to decline over the period of the study. The
projection of expenditure for "machinery supplies" in terms of
current dollars indicates a 12 percent increase by 1975 which is
wholly accounted for by expected inflationary tendencies in the
economy.
In contrast to chemical fertilizer, purchased feeds, machinery
and equipment inventories and "machinery supplies," miscellaneous
inputs (interest, electricity, veterinary supplies and services, etc.)
has a very high elastic demand. Due to the evidence of there being
two distinct trends in expenditures for miscellaneous inputs, the
data were analyzed on the basis of the two periods. The dummy
variable approach developed by Damodar Gujarati fails to reject
the null hypothesis of the discontinuity in the demand curve for
miscellaneous inputs during the 1950-69 period at the 5 percent test
level. The mean price elasticity of demand was found to be -1.22
for the period 1950-57 and -4.28 for the period 1958-69. Such a
high elasticity is probably due to a strong complementarity between
miscellaneous inputs and the increasing total agricultural plant
size, and the substitution effect due to gradually falling relative
prices of miscellaneous inputs.
A 23 percent increase (1957-59 dollars) in expenditure for
miscellaneous inputs is projected by 1975 compared to 1969. The
increase in terms of 1975 dollars amounts to 46 percent: from $72.8
million to $106.4 million.
It is anticipated that the information regarding the demand
structure for farm production input factors discussed in this study
will be useful to people involved in farm labor policy-making, and
decision making in farm supply business firms, credit agencies
and farming businesses in planning for the extension of their volume
of operations in the next few years. The future demand for these
farm inputs, among other factors, will largely depend on the trend
of their "real" or relative prices. The projected amount of expenditures
for these inputs in current dollars will be modified by any
changes in the extent of inflationary tendencies in the economy. / Graduation date: 1972
|
233 |
Economic considerations in managing Oregon Rocky Mountain elkSandrey, Ronald Albert 27 October 1982 (has links)
The size of elk herds in Eastern Oregon has become a controversial
issue. Trade-offs exist between the numbers of elk and domestic
livestock on a given area of land, and also between elk and commercial
timber harvesting policies. Disputes arise from differing views as
to proper use of the natural resource base, specifically, public
forested and grazing lands. Economic comparisons between elk and
alternative uses of the land are complicated by the non-market nature
of the elk resource, as this necessitates using a method to value the
resource which may not be familiar to many decision makers.
The objectives of this thesis were: (1) to analyze the demand
for antlerless elk tags in eastern Oregon and to use the analysis to
examine alternative pricing policies for allocating these antlerless
tags, (2) to evaluate alternative elk management strategies from an
economic perspective, and (3) to optimize societal benefits from the
land base over time.
Objective (1) was met by using the travel cost method. Results
indicate that state hunting revenues would rise substantially if tag
prices were increased so as to equilibrate quantities demanded and
supplied. Objective (2) was met by using a computer simulation model
to ascertain the impacts of harvesting and management policies upon
the herd's stability and productivity. The results, placing emphasis
on the antlerless animals, indicate that a slight reduction in current
herd levels is economically desirable. This result is caused in part
by the decreasing returns to scale from the elk herd as measured by
total harvest per 1000 summer adult elk. Limitations of these conclusions
with respect to bull elk demand are documented.
Finally, objective (3) is met by formulating the dynamic relationships
between elk, domestic livestock, and timber as a system of
dynamic Lagrangian multipliers. This allows optimal inter-temporal
allocation of resources by discounting future returns from these resources
and equating marginal benefits of present and future use. The
decision rules are examined, and economic implications of the multipliers
are discussed. Although a theoretical model, some data is discussed,
as are directions for future research. / Graduation date: 1983
|
234 |
Economic evaluation of projects and policies affecting anadromous fish : a simulation approachHastie, James D. 25 August 1986 (has links)
Anadromous fish populations in the Pacific Northwest have
undergone substantial change throughout the past century.
Historical periods of over-harvest and the construction of
numerous dams throughout the region have contributed to declines
in the runs of naturally spawning stocks. Management efforts to
rebuild fish populations have focused on the restriction of
harvest activities and the release of hatchery-reared salmon.
A microcomputer simulation model is developed to estimate
the economic impacts of management alternatives. In it, fish are
passed throughout a network of nodes, according to parameters
governing mortality and harvest. These parameters, and the node
structure itself, are provided to the model by a user-specified
input file. As a result, the model affords flexibility in
meeting the modeling needs of differing salmonid stocks.
The model's economic assessment capabilities are
demonstrated through a case study of Rogue River spring chinook.
Results of this exercise include estimates for the impacts of
dam construction, hatchery releases, and changes in ocean and
river harvest policies on the social value derived from harvest
activities. The research also examines the redistribution of
economic benefits associated with these policies.
The impact of a recently constructed dam upon spring
chinook fishermen is estimated at a loss of more than
$10,600,000 over thirty years, given no hatchery
supplementation. Current hatchery programs have mitigated the
loss to fishermen, but whether they also offset their operating
costs depends upon the particular harvest values employed. The
value of providing an additional wild spawner to the basin is
estimated to be roughly $300.
Examination of various harvest alternatives indicates that
restrictions placed on the commercial ocean fishery would be
more successful in increasing the present value of harvests than
would similar restrictions in the sport fishery. An important
factor in this outcome is the higher value attributed to sport
catch by currently accepted methods of valuation.
Suggestions are made for improvements to the simulation
model and the availability of information for use with it.
Foremost among these is the need for improved specification of
the marginal social value derived from salmon harvested in
commercial and recreational fisheries. / Graduation date: 1987
|
235 |
Strategy selection in the Oregon trawl fisheriesHarman, Ellen Jean 01 October 1987 (has links)
The ocean fishery is an example of a common property
resource industry. Behavior of commercial fishermen is
determined by a complex set of economic, environmental and
social factors. All of these factors contribute to the
individual fisherman's success.
Fishermen learn to cope with the variability inherent
to their occupation. Two strategies are observed in fishing
behavior: The specialist who operates exclusively in
one fishery and the generalist who readily switches
fisheries according to market, social or management considerations.
Traditional fishery models formulated to predict the
behavior of fishermen have focused on the specialist.
Smith and McKelvey (1986) and McKelvey (1983, 1987) have
provided analyses to suggest these two fishing strategies
may co-exist in a fluctuating environment.
The purpose of this study is to analyze the Oregon
trawl fisheries for the presence of diversification in
strategy selection.
To gather the data necessary for testing the
hypotheses, interviews were conducted in the trawl
fisheries of Oregon, June through December 1985. Three
groups of fishermen are identified according to strategy
selection. Nominal effort differences and capital-to-income
ratios are examined for each strategy type.
Additional analysis is done to look at the components
of income determination through regression analysis. Discriminant
analysis is used to examine the fishermen's attitudes
toward switching, risk and management concerns.
Among the findings of this research is that
specialists and generalists do exist but they cannot
adequately characterized by exclusively economic measures.
Attitudes shown on the part of the fishermen indicate
they feel that management is a significant factor contributing
to income variability and strategy selection. / Graduation date: 1988
|
236 |
THE INTERNATIONAL SULFUR MARKET: REGIONAL SUPPLY/DEMAND BALANCES, PROJECTIONS, AND IMPACTS ON THE INTERNATIONAL MARKET FOR SULFUR.OKECH, BENJAMIN AGGREY. January 1982 (has links)
The sulfur supply situation in the international market is expected to change considerably in the future. Previously, sulfur supply came from mineral deposits and depended on the availability of reserves and conditions in the industry. These mineable deposits have deteriorated as production costs increased, as result of exploiting lower-quality reserves, increases in energy consumption, and environment costs. In addition, less expensive, non-discretionary, abatement sulfur has emerged as a result of the enforcement of public environmental regulations, product market specifications, and transportation technologies which require the removal of sulfur from sulfur-bearing products. These developments are seen as molding the conditions in the international sulfur market of the future. The market is expected to be characterized by: (1) a potential for an abundant supply of low-cost market-insensitive sulfur; (2) the declining role of those resources which have been supplying relatively high-cost discretionary sulfur; and (3) a broader supply base in terms of both source type and geographical distribution. This study provides a future perspective of the non-communist international sulfur market in view of the emerging non-discretionary sulfur sources and the declining role of conventional sulfur sources. The international sulfur market is divided into ten regional markets, defined primarily by geographic location, production and consumption concentration. Supply is divided into: non-discretionary and discretionary sulfur. Supply and demand are projected primarily econometrically, and surplus or deficit regions are identified. Two types of projection methods are used: regression based and non-regression based. The choice of the method used for a region is based on: (1) the availability of historical data, and (2) how closely the past and future economics of a region are expected to be related. The conclusions of this study are: (1) on world basis, sulfur is expected to be in continued excess; (2) virtually all sulfur is expected to come from non-discretionary sources; (3) some regions are expected to have a supply deficit, most will have supply surpluses; (4) the co-existence of deficit and surplus regions will result in inter-regional or international trade. However, the resulting trade pattern will be quite different from the present pattern; (5) the basis for price determination and the relative levels are expected to change; and (6) discretionary sulfur will be permanently forced out of the market.
|
237 |
Economic impacts of alternative irrigation systems under increasing irrigation water costs in southeastern ArizonaÖzsabuncuoğlu, İsmail Hakki,1942- January 1977 (has links)
Increasing irrigation water cost due to higher pump energy price and falling groundwater tables is a critical problem of the agricultural sector in Sulphur Springs Valley of Southeastern Arizona which is characterized as an arid region with low annual precipitation and high temperatures. Water saving irrigation techniques, side roll and center pivot sprinkler systems, are analyzed as alternatives of gravity irrigation. Natural gas, electricity, and diesel fuel are commonly available energy sources for pumping groundwater in the area. Four representative farm size groups, five crops, and five irrigation techniques are adopted for representative farm mixed integer programming models. The problem is treated as a complete switch from one energy source to another and twelve separate sets of computer data are developed for four farm sizes and three energy sources. Sensitivity analyses based on cotton lint price and natural gas cost variations are analyzed. The results are aggregated to determine the regional level impacts of energy source changes, cotton lint price declines, and natural gas price increases. The major conclusion of these analyses is that upland cotton is a dominant crop with wheat using residual land and water. July water and available land restrict the crop production. Increasing energy costs reduce the total annual water consumption through adopting the water saving sprinkler systems and/or crops. Under the initial conditions (cotton lint price is at $58.11/cwt and natural gas price is at $.1167 per therm) the farmers generate gross returns that cover their annual total cost. Decreasing price of cotton decreases the return above total cost and annual water consumption. Wheat production changes as a complement of upland cotton, but corn production varies as substitute because of irrigation water and land constraints and relative crop profitability.
|
238 |
An Economic Study of Range Sheep Production in ArizonaPickrell, K. P., Stanley, E. B. 01 December 1930 (has links)
This item was digitized as part of the Million Books Project led by Carnegie Mellon University and supported by grants from the National Science Foundation (NSF). Cornell University coordinated the participation of land-grant and agricultural libraries in providing historical agricultural information for the digitization project; the University of Arizona Libraries, the College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, and the Office of Arid Lands Studies collaborated in the selection and provision of material for the digitization project.
|
239 |
Egg Profit CalculatorEmbleton, H. 03 1900 (has links)
No description available.
|
240 |
Alfalfa Production Practices and Cost ComparisonsRobertson, Charles E. 09 1900 (has links)
No description available.
|
Page generated in 0.0844 seconds