Spelling suggestions: "subject:"[een] GOING PUBLIC"" "subject:"[enn] GOING PUBLIC""
81 |
Performance-Studie börsennotierter Familienunternehmen in Deutschland, Frankreich und Spanien /Jaskiewicz, Peter. January 2006 (has links)
Europ. Business School, Diss., 2006--Oestrich-Winkel.
|
82 |
Preisfindung bei Erstemissionen deutscher Aktiengesellschaften unter besonderer Berücksichtigung der Performanceentwicklung /Lorenzat, Stefan. January 2008 (has links)
Zugl.: Bayreuth, Universiẗat, Diss., 2008.
|
83 |
Staying private : erfolgreich ohne Börse aus der Sicht 30 grosser privater Unternehmen im DACH-Raum /Braun, Bianca. Unknown Date (has links)
Sankt Gallen, Universiẗat, Diss., 2008.
|
84 |
Pre-IPO-Trading eine theoretische und experimentelle AnalyseKruppe, Carsten January 2008 (has links)
Zugl.: Hohenheim, Univ., Diss., 2008
|
85 |
Delisting und Aktienrecht : verfassungs- und gesellschaftsrechtliche Voraussetzungen des Rückzugs einer Aktiengesellschaft von der Börse /Thomas, Gunther. January 2009 (has links)
Zugl.: Leipzig, Universiẗat, Diss., 2008. / Includes bibliographical references (p. [502]-534) and index.
|
86 |
Three essays on banking and corporate finance in JapanPacker, Frank. January 1993 (has links)
Thesis (Ph. D.)--Columbia University, 1993. / Includes bibliographical references.
|
87 |
Börsengänge aus der Perspektive der corporate governance : die Entwicklung in Deutschland unter besonderer Berücksichtigung des neuen Marktes /Gerig, Gunnar. January 2003 (has links)
Universiẗat, Diss., 2002 u.d.T.: Gerig, Gunnar: IPOs aus der Corporate-Governance-Perspektive--Heidelberg.
|
88 |
Financial communication and risk estimate in initial public offerings : the interplay of individual, organization, and media influencesTong, Suk Chong 01 January 2011 (has links)
No description available.
|
89 |
Equity finance under asymmetric informationNeumann, Mark W. 05 1900 (has links)
The thesis investigates the link between internal and external funds in financing new investment
when asymmetric information is important. In both chapter, the entrepreneur has private information
about the value of a project and, if the quality of the project is high, she tries to signal
this to outside investors. The first chapter explores the tradeoff between using internal funds and
raising external funds by issuing shares or bonds to finance a project. The entrepreneur can delay
the project to accumulate internal funds over time from existing operations. This allows an
entrepreneur with a high quality project to reduce her reliance on expensive underpriced bond or
share issues. However, accumulating funds is also costly because of discounting and the risk that
the project disappears. The more valuable the good project, the less the entrepreneur will delay
the project, risking its loss, and so the more she relies on external financing.
When external financing is sought, the entrepreneur decides to issue bonds or shares. The
greater the value of the good project, the more underpriced shares are relative to bonds. Thus
an entrepreneur with a highly valuable good project chooses equity and one with a less valuable
project chooses debt. Combining the two results shows that for a highly valuable good project,
debt is used, and for a less valuable project, internal funds are used. External equity gets squeezed
out. Aggregate data for the U.S. confirm that corporate bond issues are a more important source
of funds than new share issued. Furthermore, most small firms rely on internal funds and debt,
rather than external equity to finance their projects.
The second chapter provides a new theory for the underpricing of initial public offerings (IPOs).
As in the first chapter, underpricing is used as a signal of quality. However, the entrepreneur is risk
averse and only underprices when she cannot sell enough primary (new) shares to raise sufficient
proceeds from the IPO to cover the cost of the project without diluting her position below that
needed to signal a high project value. Underpricing allows the entrepreneur to maintain a high
stake in the firm and still make a credible signal of quality. This allows more primary shares to be
sold resulting in a net increase in proceeds.
The model predicts that underpricing should be greatest among firms that don't sell secondary
shares (shares held by insiders) at the IPO and that there should be a positive relationship between
the firm's capital requirement and the initial return among this group of firms only. A switching
regression framework is used. The probit model is first estimated where the probability of no
secondary shares is explained by proxies for a firm's capital requirements. The initial return is then
regressed on the same proxies, conditioning on whether the firm sells secondary shares or not and
accounting for possible correlation between errors in the selection and regression equations. Strong
support is found for the positive relationship between initial return and capital requirements for
only firms without secondary share sales, as predicted. / Arts, Faculty of / Vancouver School of Economics / Graduate
|
90 |
Monitoring or moral hazard? Evidence from real activities manipulation by venture-backed companies.Liu, Xiang 12 1900 (has links)
Prior literature suggests two competing theories regarding the role of venture capitalists (VCs) in their portfolio companies. The VC monitoring hypothesis argues that VCs effectively resolve the managerial agency problem through close monitoring and restraining managers' earnings management behavior. The VC moral hazard hypothesis argues that VCs aggravate the private benefits agency problem by exerting influence over managers to artificially inflate exit stock price through earnings management. Using a sample of IPO firms between 1987 and 2002, after controlling for the magnitude of accruals manipulation (AM), I compare the magnitude of real activities manipulation (RM) between venture-backed and non-venture-backed companies. I find that relative to non-venture-backed companies, venture-backed companies show significantly less RM in the first post-IPO fiscal year. The results are robust after controlling for the VC selection endogeneity. The finding supports the VC monitoring hypothesis that VCs restrain managers' RM behavior. Furthermore, I document that venture-backed companies exhibit a significant difference from non-venture-backed companies only in the first post-IPO fiscal year. The difference between the two groups in either the IPO year or the second post-IPO fiscal year is not significant, or at best, is weak. This finding is consistent with the argument that VCs tighten their control during the lockup expiration period when insiders such as managers or founders have strong incentives to inflate earnings. By the end of the second post-IPO fiscal year when VCs exit the portfolio companies, their impact on portfolio companies' RM decreases dramatically which makes the difference between the two groups less significant. In addition, using a sample of venture-backed IPOs from 1987 to 2002, I find that companies backed by high-reputation VCs show significantly less RM than those backed by low-reputation VCs in the first post-IPO fiscal year. The results are robust to alternative VC reputation proxies. This finding is consistent with the argument that high-reputation VCs have more incentives to preserve reputation and better ability to monitor managers than low-reputation VCs.
|
Page generated in 0.051 seconds