Spelling suggestions: "subject:"incompleteness theorem"" "subject:"uncompleteness theorem""
1 |
On two topics with no bridge : bridge sampling with dependent draws and bias of the multiple imputation variance estimator /Romero, Martin. January 2003 (has links)
Thesis (Ph. D.)--University of Chicago, Dept. of Statistics, December 2003. / Includes bibliographical references. Also available on the Internet.
|
2 |
Constructive negation in logic programs /Walinsky, Clifford, January 1987 (has links)
Thesis (Ph. D.)--Oregon Graduate Center, 1987.
|
3 |
Three applications of market incompleteness and market imperfectionJitsuchon, Somchai 05 1900 (has links)
This thesis presents two applications of the incompleteness and one application
of the imperfection of the market economy. The first application, Chapter 2, studies
the decision making problem of an individual seeking to accumulate an optimal
amount of human capital realizing that the wage income derived from the accumulated
human capital is subject to incompletely insured uncertainty. In other words,
the financial market that insures against wage income risk is not fully functional.
We find that the individual's inability to diversify wage income risk tends to increase
the need to accumulate more human capital in order to elevate wage path
and compensate for the burden of its associated risk. This is particularly true when
(i) the wage income risk is positively correlated with the rate-of-return risk in the
financial market, resulting in an even greater risk burden to the individual, and (ii)
the individual is more risk averse. There are two possibilities that no human capital
is needed. The first possibility occurs when it is optimal to work as an unskilled
worker because both the burden from wage income risk and the rate of return from
education are low. The second possibility is the case where the risk burden is so
high that the optimal time spent in school to acquire sufficient human capital to
cover the risk is so long that the discounted rate of return from education is negative.
In this case, the best strategy is to invest in financial assets alone and forfeit
the opportunity to earn wage income - either as an educated or as an unskilled
worker - to avoid its associated risk.
Chapter 3 applies equilibrium unemployment theory with a frictional labor market
to study the impact of immigration on the local labor market. Markets are
imperfect in the sense that job matching takes time and recruitment is costly. We
find that labor market outcomes of both the natives and existing immigrants depend
crucially on how the economic surplus from successful matching is divided
between the firms and the workers or, in other words, on the bargaining power of
the workers. An arrival of immigrants with low bargaining power tends to benefit
both the natives and the existing immigrants. A disparity between the two worker
types in the matching efficiency also plays a major role. An inferior matching technology
among the immigrants, interpreted here as reflecting their less established
social network, lowers their wage rate and increases their unemployment rate. The
natives are more likely to benefit from additional immigration than the existing
immigrants and, when they do, the overall benefit can be decomposed into "job
creation spillover" effect resulting from the immigrants' low bargaining power, and
"job stealing" effect resulting from the immigrants' less efficient matching. The
implications on the pattern of international migration flows are also discussed.
In Chapter 4, a simple macroeconomic model is constructed and applied quantitatively
to OECD countries, to analyze the effect of incomplete insurance on saving,
growth and welfare in a closed economy. In this economy, precautionary saving motivated
by uninsured idiosyncratic shocks raises growth rates but lowers risk-free
returns. Welfare is measured by the sum of growth rates and risk-free rates of
return, not growth rates alone. This welfare measure takes the negative impact
of precautionary saving into consideration. Applied to the OECD data, three major
results emerge: (i) the heterogeneous performance of growth and saving across
the countries reflects different degrees of insurance incompleteness, (ii) since the
externality of growth on productivity was very strong in the 1960's, the heavily
constrained insurance market itself improves productivity by promoting growth,
thereby enhancing welfare, (iii) while the externality of growth became weaker in
the 1980's, the development of insurance markets lowered growth, but still contributed
to a raise in welfare.
|
4 |
Three applications of market incompleteness and market imperfectionJitsuchon, Somchai 05 1900 (has links)
This thesis presents two applications of the incompleteness and one application
of the imperfection of the market economy. The first application, Chapter 2, studies
the decision making problem of an individual seeking to accumulate an optimal
amount of human capital realizing that the wage income derived from the accumulated
human capital is subject to incompletely insured uncertainty. In other words,
the financial market that insures against wage income risk is not fully functional.
We find that the individual's inability to diversify wage income risk tends to increase
the need to accumulate more human capital in order to elevate wage path
and compensate for the burden of its associated risk. This is particularly true when
(i) the wage income risk is positively correlated with the rate-of-return risk in the
financial market, resulting in an even greater risk burden to the individual, and (ii)
the individual is more risk averse. There are two possibilities that no human capital
is needed. The first possibility occurs when it is optimal to work as an unskilled
worker because both the burden from wage income risk and the rate of return from
education are low. The second possibility is the case where the risk burden is so
high that the optimal time spent in school to acquire sufficient human capital to
cover the risk is so long that the discounted rate of return from education is negative.
In this case, the best strategy is to invest in financial assets alone and forfeit
the opportunity to earn wage income - either as an educated or as an unskilled
worker - to avoid its associated risk.
Chapter 3 applies equilibrium unemployment theory with a frictional labor market
to study the impact of immigration on the local labor market. Markets are
imperfect in the sense that job matching takes time and recruitment is costly. We
find that labor market outcomes of both the natives and existing immigrants depend
crucially on how the economic surplus from successful matching is divided
between the firms and the workers or, in other words, on the bargaining power of
the workers. An arrival of immigrants with low bargaining power tends to benefit
both the natives and the existing immigrants. A disparity between the two worker
types in the matching efficiency also plays a major role. An inferior matching technology
among the immigrants, interpreted here as reflecting their less established
social network, lowers their wage rate and increases their unemployment rate. The
natives are more likely to benefit from additional immigration than the existing
immigrants and, when they do, the overall benefit can be decomposed into "job
creation spillover" effect resulting from the immigrants' low bargaining power, and
"job stealing" effect resulting from the immigrants' less efficient matching. The
implications on the pattern of international migration flows are also discussed.
In Chapter 4, a simple macroeconomic model is constructed and applied quantitatively
to OECD countries, to analyze the effect of incomplete insurance on saving,
growth and welfare in a closed economy. In this economy, precautionary saving motivated
by uninsured idiosyncratic shocks raises growth rates but lowers risk-free
returns. Welfare is measured by the sum of growth rates and risk-free rates of
return, not growth rates alone. This welfare measure takes the negative impact
of precautionary saving into consideration. Applied to the OECD data, three major
results emerge: (i) the heterogeneous performance of growth and saving across
the countries reflects different degrees of insurance incompleteness, (ii) since the
externality of growth on productivity was very strong in the 1960's, the heavily
constrained insurance market itself improves productivity by promoting growth,
thereby enhancing welfare, (iii) while the externality of growth became weaker in
the 1980's, the development of insurance markets lowered growth, but still contributed
to a raise in welfare. / Arts, Faculty of / Vancouver School of Economics / Graduate
|
5 |
From the Outside Looking In: Can mathematical certainty be secured without being mathematically certain that it has been?Souba, Matthew January 2019 (has links)
No description available.
|
Page generated in 0.0811 seconds