Spelling suggestions: "subject:"quackery"" "subject:"backery""
1 |
Kurpfuscherei und Strafrecht /Brunner, Erwin. January 1920 (has links)
Thesis (doctoral)--Universität Bern.
|
2 |
Kurpfuscherei zu "Jeremias Gotthelfs Zeiten" und heute /Meyenberg, Heinrich Anton. January 1954 (has links)
Th. méd. Bern, 1954. / [Auch im Buchhandel].
|
3 |
Powering the modern body : theories of energy transfer in American medicine, science, and popular culture, 1875-1945 /De la Pen̂a, Carolyn Thomas, January 2001 (has links)
Thesis (Ph. D.)--University of Texas at Austin, 2001. / Vita. Includes bibliographical references (leaves 389-421). Available also in a digital version from Dissertation Abstracts.
|
4 |
The relationship of belief in control and commitment to life to cancer patients' inclination to use unproven cancer therapiesSkinn, Barbara Jean January 1990 (has links)
The purpose of this study was to explore the relationship of belief in control and commitment to life to the adult cancer patient's inclination to use unproven cancer therapies. A convenience sample of 40 lung cancer patients completed the Wallston's Multidimensional Health Locus of Control Scale, Crumbaugh's Purpose in Life Scale, Hiratzka's Alternative Therapy Scale, and a patient information sheet. The majority of participants exhibited a strong internal locus of control orientation and a strong commitment to life. Belief in control, commitment to life, and the degree of inclination to use unproven cancer therapies were not significantly associated. However, age was negatively correlated with inclination to use unproven cancer therapies. The majority of participants had heard of five or more unproven cancer remedies, and exhibited a strong inclination to use these unorthodox therapies. The most frequently used unproven therapies were anti-medicines - imagery, faith-healing, megadose vitamins, and taheebo. The rising popularity of these anti-medicines has been reported in the literature. The findings were discussed in relation
to theoretical expectations, other research studies, and the methodological problems inherent in the study. Implications of the findings for nursing practice, theory, and education were suggested. Recommendations for further nursing research were made. / Applied Science, Faculty of / Nursing, School of / Graduate
|
5 |
Läkarens Ethos : Studier i den svenska läkarkårens identiteter, intressen och ideal 1890-1960Eklöf, Motzi January 2000 (has links)
Doctors, academically educated and authorized, assert that there is more to being a real doctor than having fulfilled the formal criteria. It has been said that there is a particular doctor's ethos, which is based not only on thorough medical education but also on traditional know-how, internalized ethics and good character. This paper contains several studies of the efforts of Swedish physicians to define themselves as doctors, individually and collectively, during the period 1890-1960 and to identify the ethos of their profession. The empirical material consists mainly of texts written by doctors for doctors on different social and political questions pertaining to the profession's interests. Studying the identities, interests and ideals that have been expressed by Swedish doctors in society and on the professional and individual level made it possible to distinguish and describe different aspects of their particular ethos. The starting point for these studies was the discussions during the inter-war period – held above all in Germany but also in Sweden – about the crisis of medicine and of the medical profession (chapter 1). Developments in legislation concerning the authorization of doctors show the ambiguity of the Swedish doctor's legal identity (chapter 2). The Swedish medical profession's efforts to hold on to the concept of internalized ethics meant that formal ethical rules were not accepted until 1951 (chapter 3). A study of medical obituaries revealed that the ideal doctor was seen as a man and a good colleague with his ethics rooted in antiquity (chapter 4). The heterogeneous medical profession has not been able to reach a consensus as to a common identity or common interests and ideals. The efforts of leading men amongst Swedish doctors gain charismatic, traditional and legal legitimacy for the profession have been opposed. After 1960, however, doctor's legitimacy in the scientific field has gained ground (chapter 5). Debate concerning the ethos of the doctors served as a strategy to unite the profession and to draw boundaries against those considered to be unqualified actors in the field of the healing arts. This, in itself, is part of this ethos.
|
6 |
Läkarens Ethos : Studier i den svenska läkarkårens identiteter, intressen och ideal 1890-1960Eklöf, Motzi January 2000 (has links)
Doctors, academically educated and authorized, assert that there is more to being a real doctor than having fulfilled the formal criteria. It has been said that there is a particular doctor's ethos, which is based not only on thorough medical education but also on traditional know-how, internalized ethics and good character. This paper contains several studies of the efforts of Swedish physicians to define themselves as doctors, individually and collectively, during the period 1890-1960 and to identify the ethos of their profession. The empirical material consists mainly of texts written by doctors for doctors on different social and political questions pertaining to the profession's interests. Studying the identities, interests and ideals that have been expressed by Swedish doctors in society and on the professional and individual level made it possible to distinguish and describe different aspects of their particular ethos. The starting point for these studies was the discussions during the inter-war period – held above all in Germany but also in Sweden – about the crisis of medicine and of the medical profession (chapter 1). Developments in legislation concerning the authorization of doctors show the ambiguity of the Swedish doctor's legal identity (chapter 2). The Swedish medical profession's efforts to hold on to the concept of internalized ethics meant that formal ethical rules were not accepted until 1951 (chapter 3). A study of medical obituaries revealed that the ideal doctor was seen as a man and a good colleague with his ethics rooted in antiquity (chapter 4). The heterogeneous medical profession has not been able to reach a consensus as to a common identity or common interests and ideals. The efforts of leading men amongst Swedish doctors gain charismatic, traditional and legal legitimacy for the profession have been opposed. After 1960, however, doctor's legitimacy in the scientific field has gained ground (chapter 5). Debate concerning the ethos of the doctors served as a strategy to unite the profession and to draw boundaries against those considered to be unqualified actors in the field of the healing arts. This, in itself, is part of this ethos.
|
7 |
"That Old Serpent": Medical Satires of Eighteenth-Century BritainHungerpiller, Audrey R. January 2022 (has links)
No description available.
|
8 |
Kärringmedicin och vetenskap : läkare och kvacksalverianklagade i Sverige omkring 1770-1870 = Old wives' remedies and science : physicians and so-called quacks in Sweden, 1770 to 1870 /Ling, Sofia, January 2004 (has links)
Diss. Uppsala : Uppsala universitet, 2004. / [Ny tr.], 2005. Pp. 270-285: Bibliography.
|
9 |
Essays in Industrial Organization and Behavioral EconomicsYermukanova, Binur 16 September 2024 (has links)
In the first chapter of my thesis, I examine a domestic downstream producer that acquires a foreign input supplier with the aim of manipulating the transfer price and shifting profits from a high-tax to a low-tax country. The United States, with a corporate tax rate of 21%, is the leading example of profit shifting behavior, where multinational enterprises like Google, Apple and Facebook shift part of their profits to tax havens like Ireland, the Netherlands, or Switzerland. In our model, the multinational enterprise faces a trade-off: insourcing the input at a high transfer price reduces the corporate tax burden but at the cost of increasing the input cost of its downstream division, which reduces domestic sales and profits. The optimal transfer price balances this trade-off. In an extension that we develop in the model, the regulation under the arm’s length principle is shown to reduce the transfer price, which reduces distortion in the domestic production and expands the region in which vertical FDI benefits consumers and social welfare in the home country. We also show that promoting downstream competition could help align private and social incentives, reinforcing the positive effects of regulation. In the second chapter, I study the effect of consumer learning on shrouding (hiding information about the product price) and pricing strategies of the firms in add-on markets. The presence of consumer myopia in add-on markets often allows firms to exploit consumers who have limited information about the market, even in competitive ones. I formally develop a dynamic theoretical model of add-on markets where consumers learn about the shrouding strategies of firms after they buy and experience expensive add-on products in a previous period. Despite high levels of consumer myopia, I find that firms choose to unshroud the add-on product and sell it at a low price as long as consumer experience is high enough in the market. I also find co-existence of shrouding and unshrouding equilibria with high add-on prices when the level of consumer experience is low enough and the level of consumer myopia is high enough in the market. The results combine the contrasting results in the literature for add-on markets (Gabaix and Laibson (2006) and Dahremoller (2013)), and are robust to an infinite-period extension of the model. In the third chapter, I formally develop a theoretical model of the market for quacks, where market consists of both firms which provide a useless service and some experts. Apart from the naive consumers who sample firms based on anecdotal reasoning, I introduce some consumers who use Bayesian updating based on the distribution of firms in the market (sophistication), and hence can infer some information about firms based on the signals they receive, and study its effect on the behavior of firms in the market. In this setting, I find a Bayesian mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium, in which firms choose to randomize over low prices and sell their services to naive and sophisticated consumers, as long as there is a significant fraction of consumers who update their information based on the distribution of the firms in the market. The higher is the quality of service provided by the expert, the larger is the region in which this Nash equilibrium prevails. In contrast, if the fraction of consumers with incorrect beliefs is high enough, firms sell their services at high prices in equilibrium and only to the latter type of consumers. I extend the benchmark model to include more than one quack (and more than one expert), and the results are shown to be robust to the extensions. When there are two quacks and two experts, I find that firms may ‘split’ the market, and sell their services at different prices.
|
Page generated in 0.0363 seconds