• Refine Query
  • Source
  • Publication year
  • to
  • Language
  • 436
  • 221
  • 221
  • 221
  • 221
  • 221
  • 192
  • 133
  • 44
  • 29
  • 29
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • Tagged with
  • 979
  • 979
  • 966
  • 957
  • 946
  • 163
  • 157
  • 156
  • 155
  • 155
  • 122
  • 113
  • 61
  • 54
  • 46
  • About
  • The Global ETD Search service is a free service for researchers to find electronic theses and dissertations. This service is provided by the Networked Digital Library of Theses and Dissertations.
    Our metadata is collected from universities around the world. If you manage a university/consortium/country archive and want to be added, details can be found on the NDLTD website.
241

Trips and domestic control : implications for developing countries

Osei-Tutu, Julia J. January 2001 (has links)
No description available.
242

Globalization and the limits of National merger control laws : gaps in global governance and the need for an international merger control regime

Wilson, Joseph, 1968- January 2002 (has links)
No description available.
243

The air bridge denial program and the shootdown of civil aircraft under international law /

Huskisson, Darren Charles January 2004 (has links)
No description available.
244

Navigation in airspace - a legal trichotomy

Hornik, Jiří. January 2001 (has links)
No description available.
245

Aviation insurance

Góngora, Luis Jorge. January 1998 (has links)
No description available.
246

NCAA DI amateurism and international prospective student athletes the professionalization threshold /

Kaburakis, Anastasios. Unknown Date (has links)
Thesis (Ph.D.)--Indiana University, Dept. of Kinesiology, 2005. / Source: Dissertation Abstracts International, Volume: 67-01, Section: B, page: 0220. Adviser: Lawrence W. Fielding. "Title from dissertation home page (viewed Feb. 9, 2007)."
247

Constitutionalizing the international legal system: Trade efficiency v. sustainability.

Gonzalez, Jennifer S. January 2009 (has links)
Thesis (M.A.)--Lehigh University, 2009. / Adviser: John M. Gillroy.
248

Changes and solutions to improve humanitarian aid

Nelson, Eisha Amanda 02 September 2015 (has links)
<p> The 1990s saw a rise in the participation of NGOs answering the demands of affected populations caught in between armed conflicts, bouts of natural disasters and diseases. Though their intentions were good, it was from this point onwards NGOs have gained their notoriety, despite the work they do to address the needs of man. With a consistent rise of the number of actively participating NGOs, these humanitarian actors have since gone under scrutiny by the general population, which range from ineffective operations, scandals surrounding aid money, ethics within humanitarianism as well as many aid organizations that still remain independent from each other.</p><p> This paper will seek to answer how to improve the role of humanitarian aid in emergency situations, and address its issues and shortcomings. This will be done by analyzing the different criticisms faced by these humanitarian actors, as well as analyzing the different solutions that have since been proposed in order to answer these criticisms and find a new way for these organizations to operate and define themselves. Finally, these analyses will be evaluated and compared among one another.</p><p> Interviews have been held with aid workers and members of humanitarian organizations, in order to get a more intimate perspective of the inside workings of an NGO. Recent literature, studies and findings have also been utilized in order to get a clearer picture of the current state of humanitarian aid, notably from writers such as Thomas Weiss, Hugo Slim, David Rieff and Linda Polman.</p><p> Humanitarian aid cannot be cured with a simple solution; instead, it is an ongoing, gradual process that requires cooperation from governments and organizations in order to move forward. The non-protit sector can stand to learn a lot from the for-profit sector, especially in terms of professionalism and collaborating amongst one another. This change will not come easily, but humanitarian aid also cannot remain stagnant if they hope to reach out to populations in need with quality aid.</p>
249

A theory of interpretation for international human rights law

Hessler, Kristen M. January 2001 (has links)
A complete theory of interpretation for human rights law must answer two kinds of questions. First: Who should interpret international human rights law? Second: What principles should guide the interpretation of human rights law? Individual governments frequently claim the right to interpret international law as it applies to them, but this claim is contested by many United Nations subgroups and by nongovernmental organizations like Amnesty International. I argue that international institutions are more likely to give a fair hearing to people's human rights than are their own governments. Accordingly, we can conclude as a general rule that international institutions should be assigned authority to interpret international human rights law. The general rule has an exception, however. Democratic states that protect basic freedoms of speech and assembly will promote and protect their own citizens' human rights better than undemocratic states. Moreover, free democratic states, by giving a voice to all citizens, can take advantage of local knowledge about particular human rights problems and solutions, and so are more likely than international institutions to interpret human rights law with a sensitivity to the human rights of all citizens and to the locally important human rights issues. Therefore, unlike other states, liberal democratic states should have the authority to interpret international human rights law as it applies within their borders. What principles should guide the interpretation of human rights law? The answer depends on whether we take a short- or long-term perspective. Currently, the institutions of international law are relatively ineffective when compared to most domestic legal systems. While this remains the case, a principle allowing interpreters to use their judgment about moral human rights in interpreting human rights law can be justified on the basis of the contribution this would make to global deliberation about the proper understanding of moral human rights. As human rights law develops more effective, less voluntaristic institutions, this principle of interpretation should be phased out.
250

The global company town: An alternative perspective of hegemony, the liberal economic order, and the core-periphery gap

Bailin, Alison, 1963- January 1997 (has links)
This study introduces a new theory, called group hegemony, that explains how a group of wealthy countries maintains the liberal economic order, and how this order helps sustain the economic disparity between the core and the periphery in the post-WWII era. The theory of group hegemony advances three propositions. First, the Group of Seven (G-7) has replaced the US as the hegemon. The evidence indicates that a hegemon exists. The concentration of power within the core has remained relatively constant since the early 1960s. The US is not responsible for this concentration of power since its economic superiority has declined, whereas the power of the G-7 has remained constant. The G-7 accounts for about three-fourths of the core's power throughout the post-war era even though it constitutes less than one-third of the core's membership. In the early post-war period, the majority of the G-7's power was attributed to the US, but by the mid-1970s, power was more evenly distributed among the G-7 countries. The evidence indicates that the G-7 is the group hegemon. The second proposition contends that the group hegemon maintains the stability of the liberal economic order. The G-7 is the only group with enough power to provide liquidity, manage exchange rates, maintain large open markets, and supply foreign investment. The G-7 countries coordinate their policies when necessary to stabilize the liberal economic order. They collectively intervened in the 1970s and 1980s to stabilize exchange-markets. They coordinated their policies to offset the stock market crash in 1987. They also helped ease the debt crisis, finance the Gulf War, and aid Russia and other economies in transition. The third proposition holds that the rules governing the liberal order help sustain the gap between the core and the periphery. The rules are biased in favor of the core. These rules include preferential treatment for core members, tariff peaks on goods of particular export interest to developing countries, and tariff escalation. The liberal economic order benefits all, but some more than others.

Page generated in 0.0619 seconds