• Refine Query
  • Source
  • Publication year
  • to
  • Language
  • 2
  • 1
  • Tagged with
  • 3
  • 3
  • 3
  • 2
  • 2
  • 2
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • 1
  • About
  • The Global ETD Search service is a free service for researchers to find electronic theses and dissertations. This service is provided by the Networked Digital Library of Theses and Dissertations.
    Our metadata is collected from universities around the world. If you manage a university/consortium/country archive and want to be added, details can be found on the NDLTD website.
1

La détermination des salaires en présence de complémentarité entre travailleurs : une analyse de la stabilité d'un modèle d'assortiment

Mercier, Jean-François 16 April 2018 (has links)
Nous analysons un modèle d'assortiment, dans lequel nous introduisons la complémentarité entre les travailleurs. Dans une première partie, nous nous intéressons à la complémentarité en différenciation horizontale. Dans cette partie, il y a complémentarité en production lorsque les travailleurs sont de types différents. Le modèle prévoit alors que le travailleur rare sera l'unique détenteur de la rente économique. Dans une deuxième partie, nous analysons la complémentarité en différenciation verticale. Dans ce contexte, tous les travailleurs sont semblables, mais diffèrent par leur niveau de production. La complémentarité en différenciation verticale a pour effet de séparer les travailleurs plus productifs des travailleurs moins productifs. De plus, la firme qui engage les travailleurs plus productifs verse à ceux-ci une part plus grande de ses profits comparativement à la firme qui engage les travailleurs moins productifs. Dans tous les cas, la complémentarité et l'absence de frictions poussent les firmes à générer des profits égaux.
2

Wages and the bargaining regimes in corporatists countries: a series of empirical essays

Rusinek, Michael 17 June 2009 (has links)
In the first chapter,a harmonised linked employer-employee dataset is used to study the impact of firm-level agreements on the wage structure in the manufacturing sector in Belgium, Denmark and Spain. To our knowledge, this is one of the first cross-country studies that examines the impact of firm-level bargaining on the wage structure in European countries. We find that firm-level agreements have a positive effect both on wage levels and on wage dispersion in Belgium and Denmark. In Spain, firm also increase wage levels but reduce wage dispersion. Our interpretation is that in Belgium and Denmark, where firm-level bargaining greatly expanded since the 1980s on the initiative of the employers and the governments, firm-level bargaining is mainly used to adapt pay to the specific needs of the firm. In Spain, the structure of collective bargaining has not changed very much since the Franco period where firm agreements were used as a tool for worker mobilisation and for political struggle. Therefore, firm-level bargaining in Spain is still mainly used by trade unions in order to reduce the wage dispersion. <p>In the second chapter, we analyse the impact of the bargaining level and of the degree of centralisation of wage bargaining on rent-sharing in Belgium. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study that considers simultaneously both dimensions of collective bargaining. This is also one of the first papers that looks at the impact of wage bargaining institutions on rent-sharing in European countries. This question is important because if wage bargaining decentralisation increases the link between wages and firm specific profits, it may prevent an efficient allocation of labour across firms, increase wage inequality, lead to smaller employment adjustments, and affect the division of surplus between capital and labour (Bryson et al. 2006). Controlling for the endogeneity of profits, for heterogeneity among workers and firms and for differences in characteristics between bargaining regimes, we find that wages depend substantially more on firm specific profits in decentralised than in centralised industries ,irrespective of the presence of a formal firm collective agreement. In addition, the impact of the presence of a formal firm collective agreement on the wage-profit elasticity depends on the degree of centralisation of the industry. In centralised industries, profits influence wages only when a firm collective agreement is present. This result is not surprising since industry agreements do not take into account firm-specific characteristics. Within decentralised industries, firms share their profits with their workers even if they are not covered by a formal firm collective agreement. This is probably because, in those industries, workers only covered by an industry agreement (i.e. not covered by a formal firm agreement) receive wage supplements that are paid unilaterally by their employer. The fact that those workers also benefit from rent-sharing implies that pay-setting does not need to be collective to generate rent-sharing, which is in line with the Anglo-American literature that shows that rent-sharing is not a particularity of the unionised sector. <p>In the first two chapters, we have shown that, in Belgium, firm-level bargaining is used by firms to adapt pay to the specific characteristics of the firm, including firm’s profits. In the third and final chapter, it is shown that firm-level bargaining also allows wages to adapt to the local environment that the company may face. This aspect is of particular importance in the debate about a potential regionalisation of wage bargaining in Belgium. This debate is, however, not specific to Belgium. Indeed, the potential failure of national industry agreements to take into account the productivity levels of the least productive regions has been considered as one of the causes of regional unemployment in European countries (Davies and Hallet, 2001; OECD, 2006). Two kinds of solutions are generally proposed to solve this problem. The first, encouraged by the European Commission and the OECD, consists in decentralising wage bargaining toward the firm level (Davies and Hallet, 2001; OECD, 2006). The second solution, the regionalisation of wage bargaining, is frequently mentioned in Belgium or in Italy where regional unemployment differentials are high. In this chapter we show that, in Belgium, regional wage differentials and regional productivity differentials within joint committees are positively correlated. Moreover, this relation is stronger (i) for joint committees where firm-level bargaining is relatively frequent and (ii) for joint committees already sub-divided along a local line. We conclude that the present Belgian wage bargaining system which combines interprofessional, industry and firm bargaining, already includes the mechanisms that allow regional productivity to be taken into account in wage formation. It is therefore not necessary to further regionalise wage bargaining in Belgium. <p> / Doctorat en Sciences économiques et de gestion / info:eu-repo/semantics/nonPublished
3

Impact d'une réduction d'une année d'étude sur les salaires : résultats empiriques à partir de l'introduction des Cégeps

Dogoua, Franck-Hermann 24 April 2018 (has links)
Ce mémoire cherche à évaluer l’impact d’une réduction d’une année de scolarité sur les salaires. Plusieurs travaux de recherche ont montré l’importance des formations universitaires sur l’employabilité et les salaires. Des scientifiques ont également investigué sur la question des écarts salariaux. La plupart d’entre eux s’appuient sur des théories économiques, et tentent de répondre à cette problématique par les différents niveaux de formation scolaire au sein d’un groupe d’individus, ou encore par le nombre d’années d’expérience sur le marché du travail. Leurs résultats distincts mettent en évidence la difficulté à expliquer intégralement les différences de salaires. Dans ce mémoire, nous nous appuyons sur la réforme du système éducatif québécois survenu en 1967, pour évaluer l’impact d’une réduction d’une année de scolarité sur les salaires. Suite à l’actualité socio-éducative qui prévalait à cette époque, le gouvernement Lesage a été amené à prendre en considération le rapport fourni par la commission Parent sur la réforme du système éducatif. Nous nous intéressons donc de façon particulière au passage du cours classique au Cégep. À la base, le cours classique était de huit ans et sanctionné par un baccalauréat ès arts. Avec la création du Cégep, le nombre total d’années d’étude avant l’université a été réduit à sept. Ceci a occasionné en 1968 l’entrée simultanée de deux cohortes d’étudiants en première année d’université. Pour réaliser cette étude, nous utilisons les données de la division des opérations de Statistique Canada, sur le Recensement de la population de 1981. À partir d’une approche de Regression Discontinuity design, nous confirmons qu’une année de scolarité en moins affecte négativement les salaires, de façon significative. Cet effet est de 18% dans notre meilleure spécification. / This report aims to evaluate the impact of a reduction of one year of schooling on future wages. Several research studies have shown the importance of university training on employability and wages. Scientists have also investigated the issue of wage differentials. Most of them rely on economic theories, and try to explain this issue by the different levels of education by differences in educational attainment within a group of individuals, or by the number of years of experience in labor market. Their distinct results highlight the difficulty in explaining wage differences as a whole. In this master’s thesis, we rely on the reform of Quebec’s education system in 1967, to evaluate the impact of an extra year of schooling on remuneration. Following the current socio-educational situation prevailing at that time, the Lesage government was led to take into consideration the report provided by the Parent commission on the valuation of the education system. We are particularly interested in the graduation from classical courses to CEGEP. Initially, the classical course was eight years old and culminated in a Bachelor of Arts degree. The creation of the CEGEP reduced the number of years of study before university to seven. This led in 1968 to the simultaneous entry of two cohorts of students in the first year of university. This study uses data from the Statistics Canada operations division on the 1981 Census of Population. Based on a Regression Discontinuity design approach, we have confirmed that one less year of schooling negatively affects Wages, significantly. This effect is 18% in our best specification.

Page generated in 0.0797 seconds