Spelling suggestions: "subject:"transfer taxa""
31 |
On the economics of housing markets and urban policy: Three essays in real estat economicsFritzsche, Carolin 13 September 2018 (has links)
In order to assist governments in ensuring efficient housing markets and providing access to suitable housing conditions for all people, research about the functioning of housing markets is needed. My thesis, which is comprised of three essays that repre-sent the main chapters, contributes to the research on the economic processes that work within housing markets, especially with regard to challenges that arise from ur-ban concentration. In particular, I study the following research questions:
• What are causes of vacancies in the housing market?
• What are the effects of real estate transfer taxes on activity in the housing market?
• What are the differences between counties in the provision of technical infra-structure?
1. Causes of Vacancies
We summarize theoretical approaches, which may explain the mechanisms leading to vacancies under the assumptions of the standard market model, search and matching theory and behavioral economics. Concerning the latter, we propose a new frame-work to explain why and under which conditions homeowners are hesitant to sell their dwellings, which may lead to vacancies. In this framework, we highlight the fact that even if buyers and sellers are homogenous individuals, their willingness to pay differs depending on market developments. Under the assumptions of the standard market model, we hypothesize that vacancies only arise if the market price equals the suppliers’ minimum price. Next to that, we identify the following factors that could explain an increase in vacancies: Greater market power, higher heterogeneity between dwellings, low holding costs of dwellings, high list prices, a high share of small dwell-ings, less intermediaries and a shorter mandatory period of notice of tenants. Despite the wide range of models explaining vacancies, there is need for new theoretical frameworks.
We evaluate the identified hypotheses in the theoretical literature by comparing them with the results found in the empirical studies. Some hypotheses have either been in-vestigated by the empirical literature only to a limited degree or have not been inves-tigated at all. Next to the positive analysis of the mechanisms that cause vacancies, we need to pose the normative question, if and under which circumstances vacancies should be considered problematic. Vacancies in the short run may be a necessity in a search and matching context to reach an efficient market outcome; i.e., to offer poten-tial buyers a heterogeneous pool of options to choose from and to fit their individual needs. Additionally, with the assumptions of behavioral economics, an owner of a vacant dwelling might find greater pleasure in speculating with the object than a buyer would enjoy living in it. However, vacancies could indicate a welfare loss if caused by a monopoly that artificially reduces the housing supply on a market. A reduction of information asymmetry could reduce vacancies and increase welfare.
2. Effects of Real Estate Transfer Taxes
German states can set their own real estate transfer tax rates. To date, the real estate transfer tax rates range between 3.5% and 6.5%. Although the tax rates do not seem to be particularly high, the tax results in a relatively high tax amount to be paid; even small changes in the tax rate may cause buyers to accelerate a planned transaction to pay a lower tax rate.
In our empirical analysis of different German states, we estimate that a one-percentage-point increase in the transfer tax produces significant anticipation effects for the month just before a tax is increased (about 43% more transactions before and 44% less after) and yields approximately 6% fewer overall transactions and therefore much lower market activity. We show that in many cases, the former first-best option – to buy or sell a single-family home – is apparently no longer the optimal choice. Thus, we expect ownership rates to decrease as letting apartments becomes more attractive than selling. This questions the wisdom of real estate transfer tax increases when other political measures that attempt to support homeownership creation are in place. Addi-tionally, retired households, which tend to stay in houses that are too large after their children have left, could be discouraged from downsizing to their actual needs. Indi-viduals may forgo better job offers in other regions or accept longer commutes, which can have negative consequences on urban labor markets.
3. Efficiency of County Road Provision
When houses in urban areas are expensive, an adequate road network allows residents to locate further away from agglomeration centers. This takes pressure off housing prices and infrastructure systems in cities and supports housing markets in rural areas. I use the example of county roads to study whether counties differ in their efficiency of the provision of infrastructure. Efficiency refers to the use of economic resources (input) in the most technologically efficient manner to produce a certain amount of output. Studies on the efficient provision of roads incorporated the ‘quantity’ of roads (e.g., the length of the road network) and the ‘quality’ of roads (e.g., an index that measures road condition) as the relevant output indicators.
I address two major problems of previous studies. First, to measure the quality of roads, I acquired new and improved data on road condition by county governments. Second, I focus on the data referring to a road network of approximately the same age. An old road network asks for more frequent maintenance and thus higher costs. Therefore, it is possible that governments with an older road network in their region could be identified as less efficient than governments with a newer road network, even if they do not actually employ their financial resources in a less efficient manner.
The results of my study indicate that there are substantial efficiency differences and efficiency reserves in the provision of roads in eastern German counties: Depending on the specification, in the median county, the same level of outputs (i.e., area of roads and road condition) could be achieved using 48% to 70% fewer inputs (i.e., expendi-tures). I also find that my results differ greatly from existing studies applying proxy data for the quality of roads (e.g., the number of accidents).
|
32 |
Die invloed van kapitaalwinsbelasting op boedelbeplanning en boedelbelasting en die toepaslikheid van trusts in boedelbeplanning na die inwerkingtreding van KapitaalwinsbelastingKotze, Jan Harmse, Van Wyk, E. 03 1900 (has links)
Thesis (MAcc)--University of Stellenbosch, 2009. / AFRIKAANSE OPSOMMING: Met die bekendstelling van kapitaalwinsbelasting in 2000 was belastingpligtiges en
belastingadviseurs bekommerd oor die invloed daarvan op belasting- en
boedelbeplanning. Om die volle impak daarvan te verstaan moet die werking van
kapitaalwinsbelasting ondersoek word.
Paragraaf 10 van die Agste Bylae definieer die belasbare kapitaalwinste vir die jaar
van aanslag. Hiervolgens word kapitale winste in die hande van verskillende
belastingpligtiges teen verskillende “koerse” belas. In die algemeen word daar na
Paragraaf 10 verwys as die insluitingsartikel wat op kapitaalwinste van toepassing
is. Aangesien slegs ‘n “gedeelte” van kapitaalwinste onderhewig is aan normale
belasting is een van die grootste faktore in die huidige belastingomgewing steeds
om te onderskei tussen inkomste van ‘n kapitale of nie-kapitale aard.
Deur die toepassing van Paragraaf 10 word kapitaalwinste gerealiseer deur Trusts
en Maatskappye teen hoër koerse belas, as in die geval van individue. Dit het tot
gevolg dat belastingpligtiges en belastingadviseurs die gebruik van trusts as ‘n
effektiewe hulpmiddel vir boedelbeplanning begin bevraagteken het. Die effektiewe
belastingkoers van toepassing op kapitaalwinste gerealiseer deur individue is egter
die laagste van al die verskillende belastingpligtiges. Wanneer ‘n individue te
sterwe kom is sy boedel onderhewig aan boedelbelasting, wat ‘n verdere belasting
las tot gevolg het. Indien ‘n trust effektief toegepas word tydens die opstel van ‘n
boedelplan vir ‘n individu sal die bates van die trust nie onderhewig wees aan
boedelbelasting nie.
Deur die verskeie opsies wat beskikbaar is vir ‘n belastingpligtige, wanneer hy ‘n
besluit moet neem watter beleggingsvoertuig hy moet gebruik vir die belegging,
kan die effektiewe belastingkoerse vergelyk word. Deur die uitkomste van die
verskeie opsies teenoor mekaar te vergelyk bewys dit dat indien ‘n trust korrek
aangewend word, dit steeds as ‘n effektiewe hulpmiddel in ‘n boedelplan kan
aangewend word.
Tydens die uitvoer van die vergelyking van die verskillende opsies wat vir die
belastingpligtige beskikbaar is, is die tydwaarde van geld buite rekening gelaat.
Indien die lewensverwagting van ‘n individu in berekening gebring word kan die
uitkoms van die vergelyking moontlik anders wees.
Deur dit alles in ag te neem bevestig dit weereens dat elke individue se boedelplan
uniek sal wees indien sy persoonlike finansiële omstandighede in ag geneem
word. / ENGLISH ABSTRACT: With the introduction of capital gains taxation in 2000, taxpayers and their advisors
feared the impact thereof on tax planning and estate planning. To determine the
impact thereof the taxation of capital gains must be understood.
Paragraph 10 of the Eight Schedule define the taxable portion of capital gains for
the year of assesment. Paragraph 10 is also commonly known as the inclusion
clause applicaple on capital gains. This application of paragraph 10 has the effect
that capital gains realised by different types of taxpayers are taxed at different
rates. Due to the application of paragraph 10 only a portion of the capital gain
realised by the taxpayer is subject to normal taxation. Therefor one of the biggest
concerns for taxpayers still is to determine if income are of a capital nature or not.
The inclusion rate, according to paragraph 10, applicable on capital gains realised
by trusts and companies is higher than that of a individual and gives rise to a
bigger tax burden relating to capital profits for trusts and companies. Therefor
taxpayers and their advisors doubt wether a trust could still be used as an effective
tool for estate planning. The effective tax rate on caiptal gains for individuals is the
lowest for all types of taxpayers. But when an individual dies his estate is subject to
estate duty, which leaves an additional burden for an individual to take into
account. When a trust is effectively utilised in preparing an estate plan for an
individual, the assets of the trust should not be subject to estate duty.
By evaluating the effective tax rates applicable to the different options available to
a taxpayer when he needs to determine which investment vehicle to use when
making an investment, a comparision can be made. By comparing the effective tax
rates a conclusion can be drawn that a trust can still be used as an effective tool
for estate planning when utilised properly.
When the comparison was made the time value of money was ignored. If the life
expectancy of a individual are taken into account the outcome could be different.
When everything is taken into consideration the conclusion is that the estate plan
for every individual is unique and determined by his or her personal financial
circumstances.
|
33 |
The levying of capital gains tax at death02 September 2013 (has links)
LL.M. (Tax Law) / Capital Gains Tax (“CGT”) was introduced with effect from 1 October 2001 by the insertion of section 26A and an Eighth Schedule into the Income Tax Act 58 of 1962, by the Taxation Laws Amendment Act 5 of 2001. Paragraph 40(1) of the Eight Schedule provides that a deceased person must, with certain exceptions, be treated as having disposed of his assets to his estate for proceeds equal to the market value of those assets as at the date of death. Paragraph 40(1A) of the Eight Schedule provides that if an asset of a deceased person is treated as having been disposed of under paragraph 40(1) and is transferred directly to the estate of the deceased person, the estate must be treated as having acquired the asset at a cost equal to its market value as at the date of death for base-cost purposes, and if the asset is transferred directly to an heir or legatee, the heir or legatee must be treated as having acquired the asset at a cost equal to its market value as at the date of death for base-cost purposes. The capital gain will be the difference between the market value of a taxable asset of the deceased on the date of his death and its base cost to him, which is included in his final income tax assessment and which will have to be settled out of the estate‟s assets. There are many arguments in favour of the discontinuance of the levying of CGT at the death of a taxpayer in South Africa, which arguments become evident when comparing the South African CGT provisions regarding the levying of CGT at death with tax jurisdictions such as Australia, the United States, the United Kingdom, Canada, Botswana and Nigeria. Canada for example abolished their inheritance tax in 1972 which in that particular situation justifies the levying of CGT at death. If CGT will continue to be levied at the death of a taxpayer it is suggested that a carry-over approach in terms of which the heir inherits the asset at its acquisition cost and the CGT liability is deferred until the heir actually disposes of the asset should be followed. This approach is currently followed in Australia, Botswana and Nigeria. The holder of an inherited bare dominium will suffer at the hands of a CGT anomaly where the deceased created a limited interest, for example a usufruct over a fixed property bequeathed by him to the bare dominium holder. The anomaly that transpires is that the limited interest created by the deceased will result in an artificial drop in the base cost of the fixed property so bequeathed and there will be no adjustment to the base cost when the bare dominium holder succeeds to full ownership of the fixed property, for example when the usufructuary passes away, meaning that the same capital gain will be taxed twice. It is submitted that legislative amendments are required to provide for an increase in the base cost applicable to the bare dominium holder when the usufructuary eventually passes away. Alternatively the SARS‟s current practice in this respect should be altered to avoid the unbearable situation where a capital gain may be taxed at 2 separate instances. At least two anomalies exist when dealing with capital losses in the deceased‟s final period of assessment and in the winding up of the deceased‟s estate. Firstly a capital loss may not be carried forward from the deceased‟s final assessment to his deceased estate to be set off against capital gains that may be realised in the winding up of the estate. Secondly a capital loss incurred on the sale of a capital asset during the winding up of a deceased estate cannot be carried over from the deceased estate to the heirs of the deceased and will thus remain unutilised. It is suggested that the method followed in Canada in respect of capital losses that occurred in the year of a taxpayer‟s death should be followed in South Africa, ie that such capital loss may be carried back three years in order to reduce any taxable capital gains that occurred in those years or that the capital losses may be utilised to reduce other income of the taxpayer in his final return. It is further suggested that this method should also be followed in respect of unutilised capital losses that occurred in the winding up of the estate, alternatively the capital losses so realised must be carried over to the heirs of the deceased.
|
34 |
Rekodifikace soukromého hmotného práva a majetkové daně / Recodification of substantive private law and property taxesŠvecová, Jana January 2014 (has links)
This master thesis deals with the impact of recodification of private substantive law on property tax legislation, however, it is mostly concerned with real estate transfer tax. This paper is divided into four chapters including introduction and conclusion. The second chapter deals with recodification and the most important changes it has brought and their impact on property tax legislation. The central third chapter is concerned with the effective regulation of real estate transfer tax, which is thoroughly analysed and compared with the previous legislation. Apart from this, the chapter critically evaluates this legislation and introduces suggestions 'de lege ferenda'.
|
35 |
Kapitaaloordragbelasting as 'n addisionele bron van inkomste vir die regering van Suid-Afrika15 August 2012 (has links)
M. Comm. / The purpose of this study is to determine the desirability of implementing of a system of capital transfer tax in South Africa. The implementation of a capital transfer tax system in South Africa should generate additional income without placing a further administrative or financial burden on the South African Revenue Services. A system of capital transfer tax will replace the current system of donation tax and estate duty in South Africa. Any new system will be based on the principles established by these two forms of taxation, but should simultaneously address many of the loopholes in these two systems. Since the Margo Commission's recommendation in 1986 that South Africa should implement a system of capital transfer tax, much has been written about this form of capital tax but the government has never implemented the recommendations. However, it is certain that a system of capital transfer tax will be implemented in South Africa in the future. The current system of donation tax and estate duty is not effective in levying the taxes and earning the income for the government for which it was originally designed. Over the years numerous ways have been developed to legally avoid these taxes, which is why they are referred to as voluntary taxes (Anon, 1988:17). This dissertation consists of three parts: The first part is a literature study in which capital taxes are discussed. The distinction between income and capital is reviewed. The various forms of capital taxes are identified and the arguments for and against introducing one of them are discussed. This part concludes with arguments for and against a system of capital transfer tax for South Africa. The second part is an analysis of donation tax and estate duty as currently levied in South Africa. The shortcomings of the current legislation are discussed and legal ways to avoid estate duty are identified. The inheritance tax system in the UK and the donation tax and estate duty system in the USA are also briefly discussed. The anti-avoidance measures implemented in these countries are discussed in some detail in view of recommendations to implement similar measures in South Africa. In the third part a capital transfer tax system for South Africa is proposed. Precautions to minimise the avoidance of these taxes through interest-free loans and generation-skipping devises are discussed. Finally a conclusion is reached regarding the matters analysed in this dissertation.
|
36 |
A Model for Optimal Interspousal Transfers in Estate PlanningPulliam, Dale R. 12 1900 (has links)
The problem with which this study is concerned is that of determining the optimal transfer of property from a decedent to his surviving spouse. A secondary problem addressed is whether equity between common law states and community property states in the application of the estate tax provisions has been achieved through the allowance of the marital deduction. From this analysis decision criteria were developed to aid taxpayers and their advisors in determining optimal property transfers to a surviving spouse. Conclusions of the study were the following: (1) The primary concern when formulating an estate plan should be to determine whether any property should be transferred to the surviving spouse. The literature has stressed qualifying transfers for the marital deduction while giving minimal consideration to the wisdom of doing so. This study indicates that in a majority of estates optimal results are obtained by making no transfers to the surviving spouse. (2) Relative after-tax rates of return of the surviving spouse and other beneficiaries are the most important factors in determining optimal transfers to the spouse. This again conflicts with the literature which has emphasized relative estate sizes as the dominant factor. (3) Rates of inflation have minimal influence in determining the size of the optimal transfer. (4) Citizens of common law states are generally favored as opposed to citizens of community property states in the application of the estate tax laws. Citizens of these states have more flexibility in. planning transfers to beneficiaries and may generally do so at a lower tax cost through use of the marital deduction.
|
37 |
An analysis and exposition of the definition of property for estate duty purposes with reference to a future capital transfer tax.Delport, Mariana 13 August 2012 (has links)
M.Comm. / The first objective of this dissertation is to establish whether wealth or capital taxes are relevant to South Africa. If the answer is yes, the further objective is to identify the various forms of capital and wealth taxes in order to determine which form of wealth or capital tax would be suitable in South Africa in the future (refer chapter 2). The second objective, once the form of capital tax for a future South Africa is identified, is to determine which assets or, in other words, which property will be subjected to such a tax (chapters 3-5). The third objective is to analyse the recommendations contained in the fourth interim report of the Katz Commission of Inquiry into certain 3 aspects of the tax structure of South Africa (hereafter, referred to as the Katz Commission) and to examine the effect of these recommendations on the inclusion of property in the deceased's estate which will be subjected to such a tax (chapter 5). The fourth objective is to provide the reader with two diagrams which will enable such person to determine: whether a deceased person's estate will be subject to estate duty in terms of the current Act 45 of 1955, as amended (hereafter, referred to as the Act); and what an estate consists of (chapter 6). The fifth objective is to provide the reader with a comprehensive alphabetical property checklist to enable such person to determine whether a specific asset should be included in the estate of a deceased person (chapter 6).
|
38 |
The taxation of wealth transfers in ThailandRodthong, Ratichai January 2016 (has links)
This thesis examines the case for a wealth transfer tax in Thailand, against the background, inter alia, of the failure of Thailand’s defunct tax law on estate and inheritance (the Estate and Inheritance Tax Act, 1933). Thailand has a significant problem with income and wealth distribution, with an increasing gulf between the rich and the poor—a root cause of the nation’s ongoing political conflicts. Such substantial economic inequality is partly caused by imbalances and inequalities in the Thai taxation system, and it will be argued that the tax system requires restructuring through the introduction of the wealth transfer tax. This would be a significant tax policy initiative that may assist in tackling a root cause of Thailand’s political and economic crises. In addressing the above issues, this thesis examines aspects of the US federal estate and gift taxes and the UK inheritance tax systems. Comparisons between the criteria, rules and concepts in the US and UK systems reveal that Thailand should not simply import wholesale the approach of either country. Both systems have commendable features that may, when combined, help address the causes of the failure of the Thai Estate and Inheritance Tax Act of 1933. It will be argued that a wealth transfer tax should be introduced in Thailand, in the form of a transferor-based system, which incorporates selected criteria, rules, and concepts arising from both the US and UK jurisdictions. In adopting the proposed reform, it is essential to consider Thailand’s political, economic, social and legal contexts, including Thailand’s current legislation relating to wealth transfers, as such laws will inform and partly shape the drafting of a prospective wealth transfer tax in Thailand.
|
39 |
Estate planning : the impact of estate duty and capital gains tax on offshore assets / C. BornmanBornman, Christine January 2010 (has links)
Death and taxes are unavoidable. In terms of the current legislation both estate duty
and capital gains tax (hereinafter referred to as 'CGT') are levied upon death. The
South African National Treasury is reconsidering taxes on death as estate duty
contributes minuscule revenue, and its administration is cumbersome. Worldwide
taxation is based on either source or residence. Because of the R3 500 000 exemption
from estate duty, only wealthy individuals are generally subject to estate duty. Wealthy
individuals make use of the annual R4 000 000 foreign investment capital allowance
by owning offshore property.
The aim of this study is to document how death taxes are currently levied on an estate
which holds offshore property, given the perception that foreign property is exempt
from death duties, and also to consider the impact on taxes payable on offshore
property at death if estate duty were to be abolished. These objectives cannot be
achieved without a thorough understanding of the development and future of estate
duty, the impact of CGT on death, how selected foreign countries levy taxes upon
death, and how residents of South Africa are taxed on property situated within foreign
countries. When CGT was introduced in 2001 the estate duty rate was reduced and it
is likely that, if estate duty is repealed, the rate of CGT will be increased.
In South Africa, residents are taxed on worldwide income and capital gains. The
international perspective is that the foreign country has the sovereignty to levy taxes
on a person who owns property situated within its boundaries. An estate which holds
offshore property may also be subject to estate duty in terms of the tax law of that
country which results in double taxation in the hands of the deceased estate. South
Africa has concluded international agreements with a number of foreign countries
through double tax agreements and estate tax treaties to prevent double taxation.
In terms of the Estate Duty Act, and in some of the treaties, a rebate is allowed in
respect of foreign estate taxes paid. However, if estate duty is abolished, the
deceased estate may be liable for estate tax in the foreign country where the assets
are situated and the deceased estate may not qualify for any rebate in South Africa in
respect of foreign taxes paid. Hence, the abolition may have detrimental consequences on the liquidity requirements, and on the heirs, in cases where offshore
property is involved. It is vital that proper estate and tax planning advice is given
before a resident acquires offshore property as the tax implications may be enormous.
The current impact of estate duty and CGT on a resident who owns offshore assets is
that the said taxes will be levied either here in South Africa or in the foreign country.
The effect of capital transfer tax on a resident with an offshore asset can never be
underestimated. / Thesis (M.Com. (Tax))--North-West University, Potchefstroom Campus, 2011.
|
40 |
Estate planning : the impact of estate duty and capital gains tax on offshore assets / C. BornmanBornman, Christine January 2010 (has links)
Death and taxes are unavoidable. In terms of the current legislation both estate duty
and capital gains tax (hereinafter referred to as 'CGT') are levied upon death. The
South African National Treasury is reconsidering taxes on death as estate duty
contributes minuscule revenue, and its administration is cumbersome. Worldwide
taxation is based on either source or residence. Because of the R3 500 000 exemption
from estate duty, only wealthy individuals are generally subject to estate duty. Wealthy
individuals make use of the annual R4 000 000 foreign investment capital allowance
by owning offshore property.
The aim of this study is to document how death taxes are currently levied on an estate
which holds offshore property, given the perception that foreign property is exempt
from death duties, and also to consider the impact on taxes payable on offshore
property at death if estate duty were to be abolished. These objectives cannot be
achieved without a thorough understanding of the development and future of estate
duty, the impact of CGT on death, how selected foreign countries levy taxes upon
death, and how residents of South Africa are taxed on property situated within foreign
countries. When CGT was introduced in 2001 the estate duty rate was reduced and it
is likely that, if estate duty is repealed, the rate of CGT will be increased.
In South Africa, residents are taxed on worldwide income and capital gains. The
international perspective is that the foreign country has the sovereignty to levy taxes
on a person who owns property situated within its boundaries. An estate which holds
offshore property may also be subject to estate duty in terms of the tax law of that
country which results in double taxation in the hands of the deceased estate. South
Africa has concluded international agreements with a number of foreign countries
through double tax agreements and estate tax treaties to prevent double taxation.
In terms of the Estate Duty Act, and in some of the treaties, a rebate is allowed in
respect of foreign estate taxes paid. However, if estate duty is abolished, the
deceased estate may be liable for estate tax in the foreign country where the assets
are situated and the deceased estate may not qualify for any rebate in South Africa in
respect of foreign taxes paid. Hence, the abolition may have detrimental consequences on the liquidity requirements, and on the heirs, in cases where offshore
property is involved. It is vital that proper estate and tax planning advice is given
before a resident acquires offshore property as the tax implications may be enormous.
The current impact of estate duty and CGT on a resident who owns offshore assets is
that the said taxes will be levied either here in South Africa or in the foreign country.
The effect of capital transfer tax on a resident with an offshore asset can never be
underestimated. / Thesis (M.Com. (Tax))--North-West University, Potchefstroom Campus, 2011.
|
Page generated in 0.0829 seconds