161 |
Dose-Effect vs. Good Enough Level: A Comparison of Treatment Length and Maintenance of Treatment Gains at Follow-Up Using the Outcome Questionnaire-45Suyama, John M. 11 July 2013 (has links) (PDF)
This study examines psychotherapy response in connection to treatment duration and maintenance of treatment gains. The dose-effect perspective (Howard et al. 1986) first proposed applying medical terminology to investigate a level of exposure to a dose of psychotherapy (in number of sessions) where individuals can expect to receive sufficient benefit (i.e., 48 -- 58% of clients can be expected to sufficiently benefit from therapy by 8 sessions). The proponents of the Good Enough Level (Barkham et at. 2006) argued that mere exposure to therapy is not an effective measure for client benefit, but rather that client responses to therapy vary. They contend that instead of recommendations for attending a certain number of sessions (dose-effect) that individuals who attend psychotherapy will discontinue attending therapy when they have obtained sufficient benefit (good enough level). Archival data of university students who previously attended individual therapy were obtained and subjects were contacted via email to take a survey and follow up measure of general well being. Those individuals who completed the Outcome Questionnaire-45 were selected for the study and their treatment response was analyzed in connection to treatment duration measured in number of sessions attended. 288 met criteria for the current study, consisting of 197 women and 91 men ranging in age from 17 to 52 (M= 21). Conclusions obtained from this study indicate that treatment duration is not a factor in subjects having positive outcomes to psychotherapy. Additionally, there was not a significant difference among subjects who were able to maintain treatment gains and the number of session attended in treatment. These results offer support for the Good Enough Level model of treatment response suggesting that individuals respond to therapy differently and discontinue when they have received sufficient benefit. Implications for these findings are discussed along with limitations of the current study.
|
162 |
Essays on Trade, Transportation Costs and DevelopmentDasgupta, Somasree 06 September 2011 (has links)
No description available.
|
163 |
Parametric study of energy retrofit options for a historical buildingEl Tayara, Khaled January 2022 (has links)
Retrofitting measures in old buildings aimed at reducing energy consumption has become a widespread subject and an urgent matter to counteract the effects of climate change and GHGs emissions. The globe has reaffirmed its agreement taken in COP21 to reduce emissions in COP26. The building sector is one of the culprits with a 70 % future energy consumption forecasted by 2050 i.e., the year certain countries aim to carbon neutral (e.g., Sweden). An old building with a severe problem of energy leakage has been studied under the influence of multiple parameters such as building orientation, shading systems, location, Low-E film and an alternative energy supply (GHP). The original building’s EnU amounted to 194.5 kWh/m2•yr; the parameters were applied and orientation of 90⁰ worked best, if the building was being designed, contrary to this case. However, energy reductions, compared to the base model, were actually achieved with the application of Low-E (5%) films and when substituting the heating demand with a GHP (57.5%), LEF-GHP reached (59.2%) and a corresponding decrease in CO2 emissions. Thermal comfort was best achieved with models that had the highest energy consumption such as LEF and ES making it counterproductive in fulfilling the aim of reducing GHG footprint of Rådhuset. The economic feasibility study showed that the installation of a GHP with at least the COP of 4.0 would lead to a shorter payback period than solely applying LEF. A tailored solution of a change in the energy source such as electrified heat supply from renewables combined with LEFs would reduce the energy and emission impact of any building; this would help the building sector reach the envisioned goal of carbon neutrality in 2050.
|
164 |
Indian Principal-Agent Theory, Or, How Varuṇa Helps the King to be JustWiese, Harald 05 August 2024 (has links)
Economic principal-agent theory deals with asymmetric information.
It has two aspects. (i) If one person is better informed than another one, the former
may outwit the latter. Kauṭilya, the Arthaśāstra’s author, and other artha or dharma
authors had a very good understanding of outwitting. (ii) Economic theory teaches
that the person in command of superior knowledge may not always be able to
benefit from this knowledge. He may need the uninformed side to agree to some
mutually beneficial venture. The very fact of asymmetric information may then
harmalso the informed side. Judging from the literature surveyed by the author, the
artha and dharma literature had no explicit (openly expressed) understanding of
this second aspect. In the author’s mind, this discussion is related to the “Varuṇa
rule”. This rule (specified in the Manusmṛti) stipulates that the king is to throw
confiscated property into water. We explain this apparent waste of resources as an
implicit solution to the second aspect of principal-agent theory mentioned above.
|
165 |
Die belastinggevolge van boedelsamesmelting / Jean-Mari de BeerDe Beer, Jean-Mari January 2012 (has links)
Estate massing is one of the estate planning instruments used by estate planners,
especially with regards to marriages in community of property; nonetheless any two
people (or more) may mass their whole estates or a part thereof.
Section 37 of the Administration of Estates Act describes massed estates and
therefore it also supplies the requirements for estate massing and will be explored in
this study.
Estate massing gives rise to tax consequences that would not have arised normally.
Due to estate massing there will be tax consequences for the predeceased testator
and the surviving testator(s) and even in some cases there will be tax consequences
for the heirs. In this study, attention is paid to the tax consequences of estate duty,
donations tax, transfer duty, VAT and CGT.
The purpose of this study is to determine the difference between the consequences
of estate massing should it happen in accordance with the requirements of the
Administration of Estates Act and should it not happen in accordance with the
requirements of the Administration of Estates Act. / LLM (Estate Law), North-West University, Potchefstroom Campus, 2013
|
166 |
Die belastinggevolge van boedelsamesmelting / Jean-Mari de BeerDe Beer, Jean-Mari January 2012 (has links)
Estate massing is one of the estate planning instruments used by estate planners,
especially with regards to marriages in community of property; nonetheless any two
people (or more) may mass their whole estates or a part thereof.
Section 37 of the Administration of Estates Act describes massed estates and
therefore it also supplies the requirements for estate massing and will be explored in
this study.
Estate massing gives rise to tax consequences that would not have arised normally.
Due to estate massing there will be tax consequences for the predeceased testator
and the surviving testator(s) and even in some cases there will be tax consequences
for the heirs. In this study, attention is paid to the tax consequences of estate duty,
donations tax, transfer duty, VAT and CGT.
The purpose of this study is to determine the difference between the consequences
of estate massing should it happen in accordance with the requirements of the
Administration of Estates Act and should it not happen in accordance with the
requirements of the Administration of Estates Act. / LLM (Estate Law), North-West University, Potchefstroom Campus, 2013
|
167 |
Die invloed van kapitaalwinsbelasting op boedelbeplanning en boedelbelasting en die toepaslikheid van trusts in boedelbeplanning na die inwerkingtreding van KapitaalwinsbelastingKotze, Jan Harmse, Van Wyk, E. 03 1900 (has links)
Thesis (MAcc)--University of Stellenbosch, 2009. / AFRIKAANSE OPSOMMING: Met die bekendstelling van kapitaalwinsbelasting in 2000 was belastingpligtiges en
belastingadviseurs bekommerd oor die invloed daarvan op belasting- en
boedelbeplanning. Om die volle impak daarvan te verstaan moet die werking van
kapitaalwinsbelasting ondersoek word.
Paragraaf 10 van die Agste Bylae definieer die belasbare kapitaalwinste vir die jaar
van aanslag. Hiervolgens word kapitale winste in die hande van verskillende
belastingpligtiges teen verskillende “koerse” belas. In die algemeen word daar na
Paragraaf 10 verwys as die insluitingsartikel wat op kapitaalwinste van toepassing
is. Aangesien slegs ‘n “gedeelte” van kapitaalwinste onderhewig is aan normale
belasting is een van die grootste faktore in die huidige belastingomgewing steeds
om te onderskei tussen inkomste van ‘n kapitale of nie-kapitale aard.
Deur die toepassing van Paragraaf 10 word kapitaalwinste gerealiseer deur Trusts
en Maatskappye teen hoër koerse belas, as in die geval van individue. Dit het tot
gevolg dat belastingpligtiges en belastingadviseurs die gebruik van trusts as ‘n
effektiewe hulpmiddel vir boedelbeplanning begin bevraagteken het. Die effektiewe
belastingkoers van toepassing op kapitaalwinste gerealiseer deur individue is egter
die laagste van al die verskillende belastingpligtiges. Wanneer ‘n individue te
sterwe kom is sy boedel onderhewig aan boedelbelasting, wat ‘n verdere belasting
las tot gevolg het. Indien ‘n trust effektief toegepas word tydens die opstel van ‘n
boedelplan vir ‘n individu sal die bates van die trust nie onderhewig wees aan
boedelbelasting nie.
Deur die verskeie opsies wat beskikbaar is vir ‘n belastingpligtige, wanneer hy ‘n
besluit moet neem watter beleggingsvoertuig hy moet gebruik vir die belegging,
kan die effektiewe belastingkoerse vergelyk word. Deur die uitkomste van die
verskeie opsies teenoor mekaar te vergelyk bewys dit dat indien ‘n trust korrek
aangewend word, dit steeds as ‘n effektiewe hulpmiddel in ‘n boedelplan kan
aangewend word.
Tydens die uitvoer van die vergelyking van die verskillende opsies wat vir die
belastingpligtige beskikbaar is, is die tydwaarde van geld buite rekening gelaat.
Indien die lewensverwagting van ‘n individu in berekening gebring word kan die
uitkoms van die vergelyking moontlik anders wees.
Deur dit alles in ag te neem bevestig dit weereens dat elke individue se boedelplan
uniek sal wees indien sy persoonlike finansiële omstandighede in ag geneem
word. / ENGLISH ABSTRACT: With the introduction of capital gains taxation in 2000, taxpayers and their advisors
feared the impact thereof on tax planning and estate planning. To determine the
impact thereof the taxation of capital gains must be understood.
Paragraph 10 of the Eight Schedule define the taxable portion of capital gains for
the year of assesment. Paragraph 10 is also commonly known as the inclusion
clause applicaple on capital gains. This application of paragraph 10 has the effect
that capital gains realised by different types of taxpayers are taxed at different
rates. Due to the application of paragraph 10 only a portion of the capital gain
realised by the taxpayer is subject to normal taxation. Therefor one of the biggest
concerns for taxpayers still is to determine if income are of a capital nature or not.
The inclusion rate, according to paragraph 10, applicable on capital gains realised
by trusts and companies is higher than that of a individual and gives rise to a
bigger tax burden relating to capital profits for trusts and companies. Therefor
taxpayers and their advisors doubt wether a trust could still be used as an effective
tool for estate planning. The effective tax rate on caiptal gains for individuals is the
lowest for all types of taxpayers. But when an individual dies his estate is subject to
estate duty, which leaves an additional burden for an individual to take into
account. When a trust is effectively utilised in preparing an estate plan for an
individual, the assets of the trust should not be subject to estate duty.
By evaluating the effective tax rates applicable to the different options available to
a taxpayer when he needs to determine which investment vehicle to use when
making an investment, a comparision can be made. By comparing the effective tax
rates a conclusion can be drawn that a trust can still be used as an effective tool
for estate planning when utilised properly.
When the comparison was made the time value of money was ignored. If the life
expectancy of a individual are taken into account the outcome could be different.
When everything is taken into consideration the conclusion is that the estate plan
for every individual is unique and determined by his or her personal financial
circumstances.
|
168 |
Analysis of the interaction between the income tax and capital gains tax provisions applicable to share dealersSmit, Jacobus Gideon 12 1900 (has links)
Thesis (MAccounting)--Stellenbosch University, 2013. / ENGLISH ABSTRACT: The interaction between the income tax provisions contained in sections 9B, 9C, 11(a) and 22 of the Income Tax Act No. 58 of 1962 (the Act), and the capital gains tax (CGT) provisions of the Eighth Schedule of the Act, are complex and share dealers should approach the tax consequences of share dealing profits with caution.
The objective of the assignment was to ensure that the share dealing profits of share dealers (who transact on revenue account) are taxed correctly, with specific reference to the interaction between the aforementioned provisions. This was achieved by considering tax cases, the interpretation notes of the South African Revenue Services (SARS) and commentary of tax writers. Examples of share disposals were incorporated to illustrate that consistency is required between the calculation of profits for income tax and CGT purposes.
The guidelines laid down by case law to determine the revenue nature of share disposals were investigated. It was concluded that share dealing profits which are designedly sought for and worked for, either as part of a business operation or not, are of a revenue nature and taxable as such.
The method of identification of shares sold as trading stock is important when calculating the income tax profit, since it is used in order to determine both which shares are sold as well as the cost of the shares sold. It was concluded that the method of identification applied in terms of generally accepted accounting practice (GAAP) is generally also acceptable from an income tax perspective.
Section 9C of the Act provides a share dealer income tax relief when a ‘qualifying share’ is disposed of. Any amount received or accrued as a result of the disposal of a qualifying share is deemed to be of a capital nature, regardless of the revenue intention of the share dealer. Prior to 1 October 2007, section 9B of the Act provided similar relief to the disposal of an ‘affected share’. It was concluded that section 9C of the Act has a wider scope of application compared to section 9B of the Act.
Because the proceeds received on the disposal of affected or qualifying shares are excluded from gross income, the acquisition costs previously incurred and deducted in respect of such shares must be included in taxable income. It was determined that the amount to be included in income is the actual cost of such shares and not the opening trading stock value determined in terms of GAAP and claimed in terms of section 22(2) of the Act.
It was concluded that the first-in-first-out (FIFO) method of identification should be applied to determine which affected or qualifying shares have been disposed of. From a CGT perspective, it was illustrated that a share dealer loses the opportunity to choose which identification method to apply and is obliged to also apply the FIFO method in calculating the CGT base cost of the shares.
It is concluded that the Eighth Schedule of the Act should be amended to clarify that the FIFO method should be applied for CGT purposes where sections 9B or 9C of the Act find application. Only then will the tax profits of a share dealer be in sync with his or her cash benefit. / AFRIKAANSE OPSOMMING: Die interaksie tussen die inkomstebelastingbepalings vervat in artikels 9B, 9C, 11(a) en 22 van die Inkomstebelastingwet No. 58 van 1962 (die Wet), en die kapitaalwinsbelastingbepalings (KWB bepalings) van die Agtste Bylae tot die Wet is kompleks en aandelehandelaars moet die belastinggevolge van aandelewinste met omsigtigheid benader.
Die doelwit van die werkstuk was om te verseker dat die winste van aandelehandelaars (wat aandele verkoop op inkomsterekening) korrek belas word, met spesifieke verwysing na die interaksie tussen die voorgenoemde bepalings. Dit is bereik deur die oorweging van hofsake, uitlegnotas van die Suid-Afrikaanse Inkomstediens en kommentaar deur belastingskrywers. Voorbeelde van aandeleverkope is gebruik om te illustreer dat konsekwentheid tussen die berekening van winste vir inkomstebelasting en KWB-doeleindes ‘n vereiste is.
Die riglyne wat deur regspraak daargestel is om die inkomste-aard van aandeleverkope vas te stel, is ondersoek. Daar is bevind dat aandelewinste wat opsetlik nagejaag word en voor gewerk word, ongeag of dit deel van die bedryf van 'n besigheid is al dan nie, van ‘n inkomste-aard is en aldus belasbaar is.
Die metode van identifikasie van aandele wat as handelsvoorraad verkoop word is belangrik by die berekening die inkomstebelastingwins aangesien dit gebruik word om vas te stel watter aandele verkoop is en wat die koste van die verkoopte aandele is. Daar is bevind dat die metode wat ingevolge algemeen aanvaarde rekeningkundige praktyk (AARP) toegepas is, gewoonlik ook vir inkomstebelastingdoeleindes toelaatbaar is. Artikel 9C van die Wet verskaf aan ‘n aandelehandelaar inkomstebelastingverligting met die verkoop van 'n 'kwalifiserende aandeel' deurdat die bedrag ontvang of toegeval geag word van 'n kapitale aard te wees, ongeag die inkomstebedoeling van die aandelehandelaar. Voor 1 Oktober 2007 het artikel 9B van die Wet soortgelyke verligting verskaf met die verkoop van n 'geaffekteerde aandeel’. Daar is vasgestel dat artikel 9C van die Wet 'n wyer toepassing het in vergelyking met artikel 9B van die Wet.
Omrede die opbrengs ontvang met die verkoop van geaffekteerde of kwalifiserende aandele uitgesluit word van bruto inkomste, moet die vorige aankoopskostes wat voorheen ten opsigte van die aandele aangegaan en afgetrek is, by belasbare inkomste ingesluit word. Daar is bepaal dat die bedrag wat by belasbare inkomste ingesluit word, die werklike koste van die aandele is en nie die AARP openingswaarde van handelsvoorraad wat ingevolge artikel 22(2) van die Wet geëis nie.
Daar is bevind dat die eerste-in-eerste-uit (EIEU) metode van identifikasie gebruik moet word om te bepaal watter geaffekteerde of kwalifiserende aandele verkoop is. Vir KWB doeleindes verloor 'n aandelehandelaar ook die geleentheid om te kan kies watter identifikasiemetode toegepas moet word. Hy of sy is verplig om die EIEU metode toe te pas in die berekening van die KWB basiskoste van die aandele.
Daar word tot die gevolgtrekking gekom dat die Agtste Bylae van die Wet gewysig moet word om te bevestig dat die EIEU metode toegepas moet word vir KWB doeleindes waar artikels 9B of 9C van die Wet van toepassing is. Slegs dan is die belasbare wins van 'n aandelehandelaar in lyn is met sy of haar kontantvoordeel.
|
169 |
The Taxation on Capital Gains and the Stock Price Volatility / 資本利得稅與股價波動薛雅月 Unknown Date (has links)
無 / This study establishes a model of the stock market involving the rational speculators to investigate whether the imposition of tax on capital gains can reduce the market volatility. The finding is that the effect of tax on the stock price volatility varies according to the types of shocks hitting the market. In the cases of the issuing shock and the dividend shock, raising the tax rate could be a way to stabilize the stock market. On the contrary, when the margin-rate shock occurs, it tends to magnify the effect of the shock and therefore increases the market volatility. Thus, it could be concluded that an increase in the tax rate may increase or decrease the stock price volatility depending on the type of unexpected shocks.
|
170 |
Analýza ekonomických přínosů greenways a dálkových tras na základě metodiky EU / Analysis of Greenways and Long-Distance Cycling Routes Economic Gains Based on EU MetodologyLibusová, Anna January 2010 (has links)
Cycle tourism presents for the Czech Republic an opportunity to address new touristic segment of relative higher purchasing power and attract tourists to regions. Cycle tourism presents also opportunity for economic growth in rural, often less developed, areas. It is one of the most popular sorte of sustainable tourism, which doesn't harm the enviroment. However, there are still reservers in the cycling infrastructure of the Czech Republic. The obstacles of getting investments for its development are missing economic arguments. The aim of this thesis is to design a method to quantify economic gains of cycling infrastructure. Based on the designed methodology, a large analysis of Greenways and long-distance cycling routes economic gains should take place.
|
Page generated in 0.0501 seconds